ASPECTS OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS IN AFRICA Mark W. DeLancey Editor ~eprinted 1980 Copyright 1979 African Studies Program Preface Authors The Study of African International Re1 ations hk DeLancey Dependence or Interdependence : Afri ca in the Global Pol i tical Economy Tho.thy M. Shm and M. C&ahine Naubmy Regional Relations in Southern Africa and the Global Pol i tical Economy Ken W. Gfiwdy The Quest for East African Unity: 'One Step Forward, Two Steps Backward' 4. Gun Liebenow The Origins of Boundary Conflict in Africa I. &.uvn Boyd, J4. The AFRICA Project and the Comparative Study of African Foreign Policy P&ch 1. McGauran and Thornm U. Johnnon Index PREFACE Several respondents to a 1975 survey on the teaching of African politics courses in U.S. and Canadian colleges and universities com- plained of various defiencies in the reading materials available for their students. One of these complaints concerned the lack of a set of essays on the international politics of Africa; this book attempts to answer that complaint. Each of these essays was written specifically for this book, and thus each was speci fical ly designed for instructional purposes. We sought to provide a variety of viewpoints and methodological orienta- tions as well as essays on a variety of subjects. Our organizing principle was the needs of a course on African politics, not a parti- cular philosophical or methodological stance. Two of the essays contain discussions of the methodology by which the research was conducted and the data was analyzed. We hope that this will serve in a small way to assist students in bridging the gap between courses in methodology and area studies. The preparation of this volume has taken somewhat longer than intended, due largely to the editor's two-year research and teaching visit to Nigeria and Caueroon in the middle of the process. Some of the essays were originally planned and written in 1975, but all have undergone revision in 1978. I wish to thank Dr. Richard Ualker, Director of the Institute of International Studies at the University of South Carolina, and Virginia DeLancey, the former for the provision of financial support and the latter for the provision of moral support. Mark W. DeLancey * Columbia, South Carolina December, 1 978 AUTHORS J. Barron Boyd, Jr. is Assistant Professor and Chairperson of the Department of Political Science at Le l~loyne College. His most recent publ i cations i ncl ude a chapter on southern African regional foreign policy in Cooperation and Conflict in Southern Africa, and an article, "International Studies and the Black Afri ca tlandbook Data", in International Studies Notes. His major researcli interests are in southern African politics and African international relations. Mark W. DeLancey is Associate Professor in the Department of Government and International Studies at the Uni versi ty of South Carolina and Associate Director of the International Studies Association. He has conducted research in Cameroon and Nigeria and is currently doing an analysis of Nigerian foreign policy. Recent publ ications include articles in the Journal of Modern African Studies, the Journal of Developing Areas, and Rural Africana. Kenneth W. Grundy is Professor of Political Science at Case Western Reserve University. His books i ncl ude Guerri 1 la Struggle in Africa (1971 ) and Confrontation and Accommodation in Southern Africa (1973). He is also co-author of The Ideologies of Violence (1974). He is currently working on a study of the racial component of the South African armed forces. Thomas H. Johnson (M.A. University of Southern Cal ifornia, 1976) is a doctorial candidate and lecturer in the School of International Relations at the Unversity of Southern California. His areas of specialization include African international relations, peace research, and internation theory and method01 oqy. His current research invol ves the analysis of competing models of the international and domestic effects of political-economic interdependence among developed and developing countries. 3. Gus Liebenow is Professor of Political Science at Indiana University and a founder and past President of the African Studies Association. He has been concerned with such topics as political and social moderni zation, and the structure of dependency relationships. His publications include Colonial Rule and Political Development in Tanzania and Liberia, the Evolution of Pri vileqe. Patrick 3. McGowan is an Associate Professor of International Relations and Political Science at The University of Southern California, where he has taught since 1974. His current research interests are in international political economy and African regional subsystems. He is co-editor of The Saqe International Yearbook of Foreign Pol icy Studies. Among his most recent pub1 ications are articles in The Journal of Modern African Studies (March 1976) and International Organization (Winter 1978) on international dependence in Africa. M. Catharine Newbury is currently Visiting Assistant Professor of Government at Wesleyan University. Her research in Rwanda (1970- 71 ) and among the Havu and Tembo of eastern Zaire (1973-75) focussed on local level political change and internal aspects of dependency. She has published in Cahiers d'Etudes Africaines and Africa. Timothy R. Shaw is currently visiting Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science and the Norman Paterson School of International Affairs at Carleton University of Ottawa on secondnent from Dal housie University where he recently served as Director of the Centre for African Studies. Dr. Shaw specializes in the foreign policy and political econom-y of African states. He is author of Dependence and Underdevelopment: The Development and Foreign Pol i tics of Zambia (1976) and, with Douglas G. Anglin, Zambia's Foreign Policy: Studies in Diplomacy and Dependence (1978). He is co-edi tor, with Kenneth A. Heard, of Cooperation and Conflict in Southern Africa (1976) and The Pol i ti cs of Africa : Dependence and Devel opment (1978). THE STUDY OF AFRICAN INTERNPTIONAL RELATI OPE Mark W. DeLancey, University of South Carolina I t Exciting and explosive events have taken place on the African continent in recent years. The internationalization of the struggle for the freedom of black people in Rhodesia/Zimbabwe, the approaching success of the movement to break South West Africa/Narnibia from the colonial rule of the Republic of South Africa, and the first visit to black Africa of the President of the United States are among the many happenings in the latter part of the 1970s that have attracted our attention as citizens and scholars to Africa's par- ticipation in international politics. The purpose of this essay is to introduce some of the major topics and trends in the study of the international relations of sub-Saharan Africa and to provide a brief survey of the most recent English- language publ ications on the subject. References to books, articles and other materials published in earlier years and in other languages may be found in the various bibliographies listed under each of the subject headings below. For more general discussions refer to Mark U. DeLancey "Current Studies in African International Relations," (1976)* and the very useful work by W.A.E. Skurni k, Sub-Saharan Africa: A Guide to Information Services (1977). This volume contains six chapters on major topics in African international politics. Each chapter begins with a "substantive introduction" or essay and is completed with a bibliography. Author, title and subject indexes are included. The beginner in African courses should refer to the excellent and very useful volume, Student Africanist Handbook (1974) by Gerald W. Hartwig and Nil 1 iam M. 0' Barr. This provides an introduction to Africa and brief bibliographies for each discipline and each African state. There are several sources which are useful for keeping up with current publ ica tions. Africana Journal , publ i shed quarterly, contains bi bl iographic essays, book reviews and 1 ists of new books on Africa. These 1 ists are divid- ed into subjects, such as economic development and politics, and countries. A Current Bi bl iography on African Affairs, publ i shed in E!ashington, D. C., contains research articles as we11 as bibliographic essays. Its lists of pub1 ications include journal articles and books. Materials publ ished in Africa *Full references to each i tern are contained in the bibliography at the end of this essay. have not received sufficient attention in most of the bib1 iographic sources. However, The African Book Pub1 ishing Record, publ ished quarterly in Oxford, England, now provides reliable coverage of all items published on the continent. In each issue there are thirty to forty book reviews and a lengthy bibliographic list. There are several general studies on African international politics that provide a broad background. The volumes edited by Y. Tandon, Readings in African International Relations (1972 and 1974) contain numerous previously publ ished articles. Ali A. Mazrui and H. H. Patel, eds., Africa in World Affairs: The Next Thirty Years (1973), includes fifteen essays published for the first time. Mazrui, a prolific writer on all aspects of African politics, has recently publ ished Africa's International Relations : The Diplomacy of Dependency and Change (1977). A massive compilation of articles is contained in the annual production, Col i n Legum, ed. , Africa Contemporary Record. The contributions are all new material and they provide the best analysis of current events availa- ble. Reporting of current events is done most fully by the two monthly editions of Africa Research, Ltd (Economic and Political). D. H. Morrison, et a1 . , Black 'Africa: A Comparati ve Handbook (1972) is a we1 1 -organized collection of statistics. These data are available on tape for use in computers. Adda B. Bozeman, Conflict in Africa: Concepts and Realities (1976) is an attempt to apply a "national character" analysis to the continent. Bozeman argues that there is a single African political culture or character and that the African conception of conflict is substantial ly different from that of Europeans. She concludes that this di fference wi 11 cause di fficul ties between African and European s ta tesrnen . Major Problems in African International Relations A recent study of the ways in which African international politics is taught in Canadian and U.S. colleges and universities [Mark W. DeLancey, Teach- ing the International Relations of Africa (1975)l indicated that there was little general agreement among instructors about the way in which such courses should be organized. Some teachers used what we might call a "problem-oriented approach;" thei r courses were buil t upon analysis of selected problems in African international relations. Such topics might incl ude, for examples, Rhodesia/ Zimbabwe, the various conflicts in the Horn of Africa, boundary disputes and refugees. Rhodesia/Zimbabwe: The conflict in this territory was once viewed as a domestic conflict between black and white people in a system where whites controlled most political and economic power. Today, the view is much more complex as many western and eastern powers have begun to provide moral and material support and as the black population has become divided, with some joining the white population in opposition to other members of the black pop- ulation. The situation is made even more complex with the involvement of numerous transnational , non-s tate organi zati ons such as church groups. The domestic background to the present situation has been analyzed in several recent works incl uding Larry W. Bowman, Politics in Rhodesia: White ?ower in an African State (1973); B. V. Mtshal i, Rhodesia: Background to Conflict (1967); and Patrick O'Meara, Rhodesia: Racial Conflict or Co-existence - (1975). Mtshal i 's contribution is an historical analysis and Bowman's book is a study of the major white political organization, the Rhodesian Front. 0' Meara's volume, a comprehensive analysis, is the most up-to-date. Since the white Uni lateral Declaration of Independence (U.D. I. ) in 1965, numerous means to bring full independence to a1 1 the people of this territory have been proposed and tried. The legal colonial power, Great Britain, has attempted negotiations and economic sanctions, but she has not used any military pressure. Robert C. Good, UDI: The International Politics of the Rhodesian Rebel 1 ion (1973) provides analysis of the earl ier years of negotiations. The author was at one time U.S. ambassador to Zambia. S. Wilmer, "Ten Years of Vain Negotiations," (1972) argues that nothing has been gained for the African population through these negotiations. Also see Marion E. Doro, "A Bib1 iograph- ical Essay on the November 1971 Rhodesian Settlement Proposals ," (1973). Negotiations wi thout pressure on the whi te government would never lead to change; Great Britain requested that the United Nations impose economic sanctions on Rhodesia in an effort to exert such pressure. The val ue of such sanctions has been the subject of much discussion, but certainly a final assessment cannot be made until the resol ution of the conflict. G. V. Stephenson, "The Impact of International Economic Sanctions on the Internal Viabi 1 i ty of Rhodesia," (1975) argues that sanctions have not a1 tered the white government's pol icies. Yet the recently expressed desire of that government that sanctions should end suqgests that some serious pressure does resul t. M. Doxey, "International Sanctions: A Framework for Analysis with Special Reference to the UN and Southern Africa," (1972); Leonard T. Kapungu, The United Nations and Economic Sanctions against Rhodesia (1973); M. Stephen, "Natural Justice at the United Nations: The Rhodesia Case," (1973) ; Michael Nil liams and Michael Parsonage, "Britain and Rhodesia: The Economic Background to Sanctions ,I1 (1 973) ; and Ral ph Zackl in, The United Nations and Rhodesia: A Study in International Law (1974) provide a full background and a variety of viewpoints. The majority of authors argue that sanctions are ineffective and inappropriate, even that they are i 1 legal. However, posi ti ve views are presented in Francis Nehwati , "Economic Sanctions against Rhodesia" (1 973) and Guy Arnold, "Rhodesia: Increasing the Effecti ve- ness of Sanctions" (1973). Another type of pressure on the white Rhodesians is being exerted by some of the black national ist groups. Guerrilla warfare is thoroughly analyzed in Ken W. Grundy, Guerrilla Struggle in Africa (1971 ) and Richard Gibson, African Liberation Movements (1972). An example of guerrilla warfare escalating into conflict between independent countries is examined in S. V. Mubako, "The Rho- desian Border Blockade of 1973 and the African Liberation Struggle" (1974). South West Africa/Namibia: This territory, once a German colony, has been treated by the Republic of South Africa as if it were an integral part of South Africa. In legal terms, howeyer, it has passed from the jurisdiction of the League of Nations, when it was a South African mandate territory, to the United Nations. South Africa refused to recognize the United Nation's rights in the area and extended her policy of apartheid to the territory. This has aroused international concern and a variety of tactics have been used in efforts to dislodge the Republic from South West Africa (or Namibia as it is called by the U.N. and African nationalists). One line of attack has been through the International Court of Justice in order to have the South African presence declared i 1 legal. See Natal ie K. Hevener, "The 1971 South-West African Opinion- A New International Juridical Philosophy," (1975) ; A. U. Obozuwa, The Namibian Question: Legal and Political Aspects (1973); I. Sagay, The Legal Aspects of the Namibia Dispute (1975); and Solomon Slonim, South West Africa and the United Nations: An International Mandate in Dispute (1973). The failure of the Court to reach a binding decision led to an increase of activity within the United Nations in opposition to South Africa. S. C. Saxena, "Namibia and the United Nations," (1975) discusses this activity and its effects. That the role of the great powers acting independently of the Court or the U.N. is of more importance than the actions of those two organizations in forcing the Republic to change its policies is suggested by developments since 1976. The Republ ic of South Africa/Azania : Central to the political problems of the southern third of Africa is the Republic of South Africa, a country in which the black majority remains under the domination of a weal thy white minority. In terms of mi 1 i tary power, economic development and international concern, the Republic is the focal point of the region. The white government's pol icy of apartheid, separate development or whatever euphemism is currently being used for its policy of racial domination and divide and rule, is the key element in the conflict. Two new books provide detailed analysis of the history and development as well as the current status of the domestic political situation; see Gwendolyn Carter and Patrick O'Meara, Southern Africa in Crisis (1978) and Ian Robertson, ed., Race and Politics in South Africa (1977). Also refer to Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, Southern Africa: The Escalation of a Conflict (1976). A more complete historical background will be found in Gideon S. Were, A History of South Africa (1974). The foreign pol icy of the Republic is discussed in James Barber, South Africa's Foreign Policy, 1945-1970 (1973) and Sam C. Nolutshungu, South Africa in Africa: A Study of Ideology and Foreign Policy (1975). The latter volume is a study of the Republic's attempts to woo the black-ruled states of Africa, especially her immediate neighbors. Also on this subject are a large number of essays, for examples refer / to D. Hi rschmann, "Southern Africa: Detente?" (1 976) ; C. Legum, "Southern Africa : The Politics of ~etgnte" (1976) and Vorster's Gamble for Africa (1976); and Agrippah T. Mugomba, "The Rise and Fall of 'Pax Suid Afrika' : Historical Analysis of South Africa's Black African Fomi gn Pol icy" (1975). South African views are expressed in two articles by J. Barrat, "~etgnte in Southern Africa," (1975) and "Southern Africa: A South African View" (1976) and one by D. P. de Villiers, "Southern Africa and the Future" (1975). The latter i tern was published in the journal South Africa International which seems both in appearance and subject matter to be modeled after the U.S. journal Foreign Affairs. South Africa has made several attempts to open ties with African states. Listeners to the international broadcast of Radio South Africa receive the strong impression that South Africa intends to become a major power throughout the continent. Comnercial investments, financial and technical aid, and surplus food are all promised to potentially friendly states. South Africa wishes to be in Africa what the United States wishes to be in Latin America. This role of continental or sub-continental leader is put in theoretical terms in much of the "dependency" literature, discussed below, and in the various articles using the sub-system concept. Examples of the latter include Larry W. Bowman, "The Subordi- nate State System of Southern Africa" (1968); Richard Dale, "President Sir Seretse Khama, Botswana 's Forei gn Pol icy, and the Southern African Subordinate State System" (1976); Tim Shaw, "Southern Africa: Co-operation and Conflict in an International Sub-system," (1974); and T. M. Shaw and Kenneth A Heard, - Co- operation and Conflict in Southern Africa: Papers on a Regional Subsystem (1976). The limits to South Africa's peaceful intentions in developing her regional role are analyzed in two essays describing her invasions of Angola: Robin Hallet, "The South African Intervention in Angola, 1975-76" (1978) and J. Barratt, The Angolan Conflict (1976). "Racism and Fascism in the Southern Atlantic" (1978), written by Sirgio Sierra, a member of the Communist Party of Uruguay, discusses the growing links between South Africa and fascist dicta- torships in Latin America. At least as sinister are the implications suggested by Zdenek Cervenka and Barbara Rogers, The Nuclear Axis : Nuclear Col laborati on between West Germany and South Africa (1977). It is now generally acce:ted that the Republic is capable of producing nuclear weapons. What is not yet clear is the role of Germany, the U.S.A. and other western countries in assisting the Republ ic in attaining that capability. Three outstanding books analyze aspects of the international campaign to overthrow the racist regime of South Africa. Richard E. Lapchick, The Politics of Race and International Sport: The Case of South Africa (1975) describes the international campaign to isolate South Africa from a1 1 aspects of international athletics. This might be compared with Richard Thompson, Retreat from Apartheid: New Zeal and's Sporting Contacts with South Africa (1976). Richard E. Bissell , Apartheid and International Organizations (1977) analyzes the campaign against apartheid in the United Nations and concludes that, although there has been much talk and numerous resolutions have been passed, the pressure exerted through the U.N. has had little effect on South Africa's pol icies. A much more optimistic view is expressed in George W. Shepherd, Jr. , Anti -Aparthei d: Transnational Conflict and Western Pol icy in the Liberation of South Africa (1977), an examination of the role of private international organizations (or "transnationals") in the campaign. Further references may be found in Mark W. DeLancey, "The International Relations of Southern Africa: A Review of Recent Studies" (1976) and chapter 5 of Skurni k (1977). The Indian Ocean and the Horn of Africa: Much of the discussion about southern African issues is involved in the larger debate over U.S. and western strategic interests in Africa, especially in respect of the important Cape, Indian Ocean and Red Sea maritime routes. With the decline in influence of the 01 d European col oni a1 powers - especi a1 ly Britain, France, Be1 gi um and Portugal - some observers have argued that the United States must in some way "fill the vacuum" or replace in some manner the departing major powers in the area. Coupled with this is the suggestion that the Soviet Union is moving quickly to fill that vacuum and that they may preempt (or may have preempted) the western powers. Tom J. Farer, War Clouds on the Horn of Africa: A Crisis for Detente (1975); Michael A. Samuels, ed., The Horn of Africa (1978); and Peter Schwab, "Cold War on the Horn of Africa" (1978) provide a variety of viewpoints on the implications of the situation. C.A. Crocker, "The African Dimension of Indian Ocean Policy" (1976) argues that the U.S.A. had been complacent about events in this region until the Angolan civil war; the U.S.A. now seems to be becoming more competitive. M. Bezboruah, US Strategy in the Indian Ocean (1977) suggests that the Americans have inflamed competition in the area because of their exaggerated fears of Soviet expansionism. Geoffrey Jukes, The Indian Ocean in Soviet Naval Pol icy (1972) agrees. Also see J.B. Bell, "Strategic Implications of the Soviet Presence in Somalia" (1975). A Tanzanian diplomat expresses an African view in A.D. Hassan, "Big Power Rivalry in Indian Ocean" (1976). Boundary Disputes and Refuqees: When you look at a map of today's Africa you are seeing a collection of states the boundaries of which were mainly drawn by Europeans, to serve European purposes, on the basis of European power politics. Very 1 i ttle concern for African interests or needs was included in the process. As discussed in detail in the essay by Barron Boyd in this book, many analysts have suggested that the artificial nature of these boundaries, their lack of congruence with African political, economic and cultural realities, would lead to numerous cases of interstate conflict in Africa. R.L. Kapil, "On the Conflict Potential of Inherited Boundaries in Africa" (1966) establ i shes several useful categories of boundaries. Kapil then relates each type of boundary to its confl ict potential . A.O. Chukwura, "Organization of African Unity and African Territorial and Boundary Problems, 1963-1973" (1975) describes the role of the major continen- tal international organization in the boundary dispute problem. Two vol umes are devoted to thi s problem: Saadia Touval , The Boundary Pol i tics of Independent Africa (1972) and Carl G. Widstrand, ed., African Boundary Problems (1969). The latter volume is one of several that have resulted from annual conferences at the Scandanavian Institute of African Studies. Another volume in the same series, Zdenek Cervenka, ed. , Land-Locked Countries of Africa (1973), is a1 so relevant to this topic. Because of the unusual manner in which colonial boundaries were determi ned and because these became the borders of i ndependent Afri ca , there i s an unusual1.y high number of states in Africa that have no access to the sea. Much of African history has been characterized by large-scale movements of people over the continent. Such movements continue today, in part as a response to natural disasters such as the Sahel ian drought of recent years and in part as a result of man-made disasters such as wars, economic upheavals and political strife. A brief introduction to this topic is N. Rubin, "Africa and Refugees" (1974). P. E. Chartrand, "The Organization of African Uni ty and African Refugees: A Progress Report" (1975) describes the efforts of the O.A.U. to improve the living conditions of refugees residing in its member states. The role of the U.N. is discussed in the comprehensive study by Louise W. Holborn, Refugees; A Problem of our Time: The Work of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refuqees (1975). An earlier work, Hugh C. Brooks and Yassin El-Ayouty, eds., Refugees South of the Sahara: An African Dilemma (1970) contains sever.1 essays on various aspects of the topic. Rhodesia, the Horn, refugees and the other problems discussed in this section are only a few of the many situations of importance to the recent history of African international relations. T.A. Marks, "Spanish Sahara: Background to Conflict," (1976) discusses another. However, those considered in this section are the most important, both in terms of their significance to African politics and in terms of their significance to the published 1 iterature on African politics. The Foreign Policies of African States A major topic in any course on African international relations is the foreign policies of African states. Research and publication in this topic can be divided into two categories: studies pertaining to one state (case studies) and studies pertai ni ng to several states (comoarati ve studies ) . Olajide Aluko, ed., The Foreign Policies of African States (1977) attempts to bridge the gap between case and comparative study. The volume contains analyses of the foreign policies of eleven states - Algeria, Egypt, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guinea, Ivory Coast, Kenya, Nigeria, Tanzania, Zambia and Zaire - written by ten authors. But, the editor has also written a comparative essay drawing on the eleven cases as data. Case Studies: Nigeria, with its large population, relatively broad resource base and large army, is one of the major powers on the continent. Although this state played a passive role in the early years of its independence, it has come to play an active leadership role in continental affairs, especially since the conclusion of its civil war. As a result of its position in African affairs and as a result of the relatively large number of Nigerian academics, there are a large number of pub1 ications on her foreign policy behavior. Two books by Nigerian authors are particularly important: A.B. Akinyerni , Foreign Pol icy and Federalism: The Nigerian Experience (1974) and G.J. Idang, Nigeria: Internal Politics and Foreign Policy (1973). Both devote most of their attention to the more passive period of Nigeria's foreign pol icy. B. Adebisi , "Nigeria's Relations with South Africa, 1960-1975" (1977) ; R.A. Akindele, "The Conduct of Nigeria's Foreign Relations" (1973); I.A. Gambari, "Nigeria and the World: A Growing Internal Stabi 1 i ty, Wealth and External Influence" (1975) ; James Maya1 1, "Oi 1 and Nigerian Foreign Policy" (1976); and 0. Ogunbadejo, "Nigeria and the Great Powers: The Impact of the Civil Liar on Nigerian Foreign Relations" (1976) are examples of the many journal articles available that analyze the more active period. Zambia i s another state that has received considerable attention from scholars. Her location as a land-locked state, partially surrounded by white- dominated regimes, and her border position between the eastern and southern African groupings of states are the causes of this attention. President Kuanda has made definite efforts to pull his country away from the influence and domination of the Republic of South Africa. For this move he is cheered by some writers but condemned for half measures by others. Two major books are available: Richard Hal 1, The Hi gh Price of Pri ncipl es : Kaunda and the Whi te South (1973) and Jan Pettman, Zambia: Security and Conflict (1974). The Pettman vol urne contains an extensive bib1 iography. Timothy Shaw, one of the contributors in this collection of essays, has conducted research on Zambia's foreign policy. In his "The Foreign Pol icy System of Zambia" (1976) he examines the processes whereby Zambian policy decisions are made. In "The Foreign Policy of Zambia: Ideology and Interests" (1976) he discusses the relationships between the national ideology of humanism and the content of Zambia's foreign policy. His comprehen- sive essay, "Dependence and Underdevelopment: The Development and Foreign Pol icies of Zambia" (1976) relates Zambian pol icies to the dependent position that country occupies in the international economic system. Shaw has also con- tri buted an essay on Zambia to the volume edited by A1 uko (1977). The essays by Shaw might be compared with the views expressed in Marion Bone, "The Foreign Policy of Zambia" (1973). Also see B. V. Mtshali, "The Zambian Foreign Service, 1964-1972" (1975) and Seidman and Seidman (1978). Zambia's attempts to break away from South African domination might be compared to Malawi's policy of accomnodation with her white neighbor as discussed in Carolyn McMaster, Malawi : Foriegn Pol icy and Development (1975). Zambia and Malawi, as well as Botswana, Lesotho and Swaziland, are compared in P. Wallensteen, "Dealing with the Devil: Five African States and South Africa" (1971). Other recent case studies of African foreign policies include Willie Henderson, "Independent Botswana: A Re-Appraisal of Forei gn Pol icy Options" (1974); R.T. Libby, "External Co-optation of a Less Developed Country's Policy- Making: The Case of Ghana, 1969-1972" (1976) William Minter, "Major Themes in Mozambican Foreign Relations, 1975-1977" (1978) ; J. J. Okumu, "Some Thoughts on Kenya's Foreign Policy" (1973); R.C. Pratt, "Foreign Policy Issues and the Emergence of Social ism in Tanzania, 1961-8" (1975) ; T. Shaw, "African States and International Stratification: The Adaptive Forei gn Pol icy of Tanzania" (1974); R.P. Stevens, "The 1972 Addis Ababa Agreement and the Sudan's Afro- Arab Policy" (1976); and Yashpal Tandon, "An Analysis of the Foreign Policy of African States: A Case Study of Uganda" (1974). Comparative Studies: These studies draw upon the experiences of more than one state in deriving conclusions. Most of the comparative studies listed here use statistics or "quantification" in making more explicit the comparisons and relationships they discuss. However, as is clearly shown in the following excel- lent essays, quantification is not necessary for good comparati ve studies: T. M. Shaw, "Discontinuities and Inequalities in African International Relations" and P. Wallensteen, "Dealing with the Devil: Five African States and South Africa" (1975). Shaw argues that Africa has become a continent of unequal actors and that the myth of equal states is now unteneable. Wallensteen compares Botswana, Lesotho, Swazi land, Ma1 awi and Zambia and their relationships with South Africa. Also see the excellent essay V.B. Khapoya, "Determinants of African Support for African Liberation Movements : A Comparati ve Analysis" (1976). Patrick J. McGowan is one of the leading proponents and practioners of the comparative study of foreign policy. His essay in this book presents his argument in favor of the comparative method and describes the quantitative data set, an "events" data set, that he has developed for this purpose. Barron Boyd's essay in this volume uses that data set. Further research based on this data is pre- sented in P. J. McGowan and K. P. Gottwald. "Small State Foreign Policies: A Comparati ve Study of Participation, Confl ict, and Pol i tical and Economic Dependence in Black Africa" (1975). R. Vengroff, "Neo-colonial ism and Pol icy Outputs in Africa" (1 975) tests the hypothesi s that decision making in African governments is ci rcumscri bed by foreign economic domination (neocol oni a1 ism) . He finds that mil i tary and foreign policies are subject to external control and con- cl udes that economic development and pol i tical independence are unobtainable goals for African states. Two comparative, quantitative studies are concerned with the hypothesis that domestic instability is related to foreign policy behavior, but both find little support for the relationship: S.A. Gitelson, "Why Do Small States Break Diplomatic Relations with Outside Powers? Lessons from the African Experience" (1974) and R. Vengroff, "Instability and Foreign Policy Behavior: Black Africa in the UN" (1976). However, Raymond W. Copson, "Foreign Pol icy Conflict among African States, 1964-1969" (1973), finds that such a relation- ship exists. His study uses an events data set, al though not the set developed by McGowan. These results should be compared with those of J .N. Coll ins, "Foreign Conflict Behavior and Domestic Disorder in Africa" (1973) and Copson's later essay, "African International Pol i tics : Underdevelopment and Confl i ct i n the Seventies" (1978). Other comparati ve studies incl ude A.H.M. Ki rk-Greene, "Diplomacy and Diplomats: The Formation of Foreign Service Cadres in Black Africa" (1974) and B. W. Tomlin and M.A. Buhlman, "Relative Status and Foreign Policy: Status Partitioning and the Analysis of Relations in Black Africa" (1977). Middle East Relations : The Middle East confl ict has had ramifications throughout the African continent and there has been active competi tion between Israel and the Arab states for African diplomatic support. Z. Cervenka, "The Emergence and Si gni f i cance of the Afri can-Arab Sol i dari ty" (1 974) suggests that 1973 marks a major turning point in this competition. The Organization of African Unity (O.A.U.) came out in favor of the Arabs and many African states followed suit. The history of these changing relations is outlined in J.C. Miller, "African-Israeli Relations: Impact on Continental Unity" (1975). Two studies have relied on analysis of African votes at the United Idations to measure changes in African policies. Samuel Decalo, "Africa and the UN Anti-Zionism Resolution: Roots and Causes" (1976) and R. Kochan, S.A. Gitelson and E. Dubeck, "Black African UN Voting Behavior on the Middle East Conflict" (1975) both argue that no simple, unicausal explanation of the African pol icy shift is satisfactory. V. J. Be1 fig1 io, "Israeli Foreign Aid Proprams to Africa" (1976) claims that there is a single cause for this change; he argues that Arab petrodollars have bought the Africans. Also see Michael Curtis and Susan A. Gi telson, Israel in the Third World (1976) and E.P. Skin- ner, "African States and Israel : Uneasy Relations in a World of Crises" (1975). The author of the last piece is a scholar who has served as U.S. ambassador to Upper Vol ta. Ali A. Mazrui, "Black Africa and the Arabs" (1975) is an outstanding essay on the relationships between the Arab world and black Africa. He states: Black Africa and the Arab world have been linked by a fluctuating pattern of economic and cultural connec- tions for at least 12 centuries. In the secular field the Arabs have up to this time played two major roles in black Africa: first as accomplices in African en- slavement, and then in the twentieth century as allies in African 1 iberation. In the past several years they have bui 1 t this a1 1 iance into a comprehensive pol i ti cal partnership, aimed at maintaining a solid front, par- ticularly with regard to the Middle East and Southern Africa. The critical question for the future is whether the Arabs will also become partners in African development. (p. 725). Two books provide extensive coverage of the history of these relationships: E. C. Chibwe, Afro-Arab Relations in the New World Order (1978) and Tareq Y. Ismael, The U.A.R. in Africa: Egypt's Policy under Nasser (1971). Brief- er analyses of developments in recent years are found in A. Akinsanya, "The Afro-Arab Alliance: Dream or Reality" (1976); A. K. Bakri , "The Economic Factor in African-Arab Relations" (1976/77) ; and M. A. El-Khawas, "African- Arab Solidarity: The Emergence of a New A1 1 iance" (1975). International Organization and Integration: There are at 1 east three aspects of international organization which are of great importance to the study of African foreign policy. First, for many African states, especial- ly the smaller and poorer states, a very large proportion of foreign policy activity is carried out at the United Nations and, to a lesser extent, the O.A.U. Second, the O.A.U. plays an increasingly important role in continen- tal affairs and in the development of an African pol icy for relations with the outside world. And, third, Africa has been a major location of experi- mentation with regional functional and pol i tical uni ty through international organi za ti on. A good starting point for the study of the roles of international orga- ni zation in Africa is Yassin El-kyouty, Africa and International Organiza- tion (1974). Moses E. Akpan, African Goals and Diplomatic Strategies in the - United Nations (1976) presents evidence of the way in which many African states use the U.N. as their major foreign policy instrument. Also see Bissell (1977) for analysis of the anti-apartheid campaign waged by African states at the U.N. Vengroff (1976) and Kochan, Gitelson and Dubek (1975) are the latest of a large number of analyses of African voting in the U.N. Interactions and the division of labor between the U.N. and the O.A.U. are considered in Berhanykun Andemicael , The OAU and the UN (1975). The tenth anni- versary of the O.A.U. in 1973 served to stimulate the publication of several studies of its effectiveness and its mode of operation: Z. Cervenka, The Un- finished Quest for Unity: Africa and the OAU (1977); Yassin El-Ayouty, ed., The Organization of African Unity after Ten Years (1975); and M. Wolfers, Politics in the OAU (1976). Col in Legum presents a very positive assessment of the Orga- nization in his "The Organization of African Unity: Success or Failure?" (1975). And, specific aspects of the Organization's activities are considered in Z. Cervenka, "Major Policy Shifts in the OAU" (1974); P.E. Chartrand (1975); A. 0. Chukwura, 1975; 0. C. Eze, "Prospects for International Protection of Human Rights in Africa" (1974); 0. S. Kamanu, "Secession and the Light to Self-Determination: An OAU Dilemma" (1974); B. David Meyers, "Intraregional Conflict Management by the OAU" (1974); D. Nworah, "The Integration of the Commission for Technical Co-operation in Africa with the OAU: The Process of Merger and the Problems of Institutional Rival ry and Complementari ty" (1976) ; and James H. Pol hemus, "The Provisional Secretariat of the OAU, 1963-1964" (1974). For further references, see B. David Meyers, "The Organization of African Unity: An Annotated Bi bl iography" (1974) ; Ronald K. Nagel , "Documentary Resources of the OAU" (1970); and Skurnik (1977), Chapter 1. In addition to the organizations at the continental or near-continental level, there have been numerous attempts to build at a smaller or regional level, both in political and economic affairs. Some impression of the number, the functional variety and the political implications of these regional experiments can be gained with a glance at the four volume work by Louis B. Sohn, African Regional Orga- nization: History, Literature and Basic Documents (1971 ). L. K. Mytelka, "A Genealogy of Francophone West and Equatorial African Regional Organizations" (1974) provides such an insight for the French-speakinq states of the continent. This essay provides brief descriptions of several organizations, a substantial bib1 io- graphy and an analysis of the problems that such organizations face with the national se1 f-interest of member states and competi tion between the members. For further analysis of one of the organizations Mytelka considers, see W. A. Ndongko, "Trade and Development Aspects of the Central African Customs and Economic Union" (1975). The various institutions formed by three East African states - Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda - have been subjected to more thorough analysis than any of the other regional groupings of Africa. As described by J. Gus Liebenow in his essay in this book, these states have had a long period of involvement in and an usually diverse variety of regional institutions. For some years East Africa was viewed as progressing toward political as we1 1 as functional integration. Recent events have greatly disappointed observers. In addi tion to Liebenow's article, see Susan A. Gitelson, "Can the United Nations Be an Effective Catalyst for Regional Integration? The Case of the East African Comnuni ty" (1 973) ; F. I. Ni xson, Economic Integration and Industrial Location: An East African Case Study (1973); and I. Sharkansky and 0. L. Doresang, "Inter- national Assistance: Its Variety, Coordination, and Impact among Pub1 i.: Corpora- tions in Kenya and the East African Cormunity" (1974). In the last few years, attention and hopes have focused on West Africa where the Economic Communi ty of West African States (ECOWAS) has formed largely under the leadership of Nigeria. tiowever, ECOWAS is so young that no research on it has been published. Description and commentary may be found in numerous notes in West Africa and other current events journals covering African events. Some background information is located in G. C. Abangwu, "Systems Approach to Regional Integration in West Africa" (1975) and Adebayo Adedeji , "Prospects of Regional Economic Co-operation in West Africa" (1970). Many analysts studying regional integration use transactions between the states being considered as a measure of integration or disintegration. In the African case such measures are often difficult to use because of the lack of re1 iable statistics on legitimate transactions and the very large number of i l legi tirnate transactions. For one aspect of the former problem refer to N. Sudarkasa, "Commercial Migration in West Africa, with Special Reference to the Yoruba in Ghana" (1974-1975). Suggestive of the importance of the latter problem is 3. D. Collins, "The Clandestine Movement of Groundnuts across the Ni ger-Ni geria Boundary" (1976). Underlying the activities of the O.A.U. and of the various regional organi- zations is a widely discussed philosophy of African unity, a belief that in some way at some time the numerous states of Africa must give up some or all of their sovereign prerogatives so that they work together from a position of strength. This plea for united action is put forth in Kwame Nkrurnah, Africa Must Unite (1963). Colin Leguv, Pan-Africanism (1965) is the best history of the develooment of this philosophy. A1 so see Adekunl e Ajal a, Pan-Africanism: Evol ution, Progress and Prospects (1973) and P.O. Esedebe, "What is Pan-Africanism?" (1977). Nkrumah's book is a politician's call to his people to take action, but R. H. Green and Ann Seidman, scholars influenced by Nkrurnah, present the intellectual case to support that call in their important book, Unity or Poverty? The Economics of Pan-Africanism (1 968). Further references to this subject are found in A1 ice Hoover, "Pan-Africanism: A Selective Bibliography" (1971 ) and "Pan-Africanism, Unity, and Foreign Pol icy ," chapter 1 of Skurni k (1977). The European Economic Corrmuni ty: A major focus of interaction for an African state is its relations with the former colonial power. A special aspect of this has been the question of the appropriate relationship for an African state with the European Economic Communi ty (E.E.C. ) . In the view of some politicians and scholars, association between an African state and the E.E.C. is valuable to the African Country because it will increase trade, aid and overall economic develop- ment. For others, however, such association is seen as injurious to the African state because it continues African dependence upon the European powers and, there- fore, maintains the present international division of labor - which keeps Africa at the bottom of the i nternational economic hierarchy. Among recent scholarly essays on this question are Adeoye Akinsanya, "The European Common Market and Africa" (1976) ; E. C. Djamson, The Dynamics of Euro-African Co-operation (1976) ; J. Gal tung , "The ~omc and Neo-Capi tal i srn" (1976) ; R. H. Green, "The ~ome~~onvention: Dependence or Departure toward Collective Self-Re1 iance?" (1 976) ; I. V. Gruhn, "The ~omg : Inching towards Interdependence" (1976); H. Hveern and 0. K. Hol the, "EEC and the Third World" (1972); and W. A. Ndongko, "From Economic Domination to Association: Africa in the EEC" (1976). Dependency Theory and Neocolonial ism: Some instructors teaching African i nterna t-ional re1 ati ons have abandoned the "probl em-oriented approach" and have organized their course around some theoretical approach. One of the most popular of these has been the application of systems analysis to the international relations of regions of the world as discussed in I. William Zartman, "Africa as a Subordinate System in International Relations" (1967) and in his "Africa" (1976). Some scholars have begun to use dependency theory, borrowed to a large extent from the study of Latin American politics. The Grundy and Shaw essays in this volume rely heavily on this conception. A key essay in the introduction of dependency theory to the study of African international relations is "Dependence in an Interdependent World: The Limited Possibilities of Transformation within the Capitalist World Economy" 4 (1974) by Immanuel Wallerstein. The dependency theme has been developed by a number of authors, but Tim Shaw has perhaps been the most prolific of these. His articles stress the irn- portant interplay between African international (and domestic) politics and the international economic order. He argbes that all of the African states are linked in a dependent relationship to the large capitalist powers of the west. Some African states play an intermediate role in this relationship, being exploited by the western powers but exploiting, in turn, the smaller and weaker states surrounding them. This theme is developed in his "Kenya and South Africa: ' Subimperial ist States' " (1977). Also see Ken Grundy, "Intermediary Power and Global Dependency: The Case of South Africa" (1976). Other authors have sug- gested Nigeria, Ivory Coast and even Zaire as players of this intermediate role. Shaw (1975b) and Shaw, "The Pol i tical Economy of African International Relations" (1 975) present a general overview of African dependency. The latter essay is the shorter discussion. In T. M. Shaw and M. J. Grieve, "The Political Economy of Resources: Africa's Future in the Global Economy" (1978) the authors "analyze Africa's place in the global economy - paying particular attention to the impact of the environment on its development prospects - and [they] examine different projections of its future problems and opportunities." An interesting companion to this essay is Ronald Prain, "Metals and Africa: Economic Power in an International Setting" (1978) in which Africa's mineral wealth is analyzed, Africa's importance as a supplier of minerals to the world is assessed, and Africa's potential for pol i tical -economic influence is considered. Also see Leslie L. Rood, "Foreign Investment in African Development" (1978). Chester A. Crocker, "Military Dependence: The Colonial Legacy in Africa" (1974) P. J. McGowan and K. P. Gottwal d (1975); S. M. Smith, "Economic Dependence and Eco- nomic Empiricism in Black Africa" (1977); and R. Vengroff (1975) are recent explora- tions of the dependency concept. Dependency theory suggests that African underdevelopment is a result of the structure of the world economy. This is related to the African and third world demand that there be a new international economic order. Zdenek Cervenka, "Africa and the New International Economic Order" (1976) and J. P. Renninger, "After the Seventh Special General Assembly Session: Africa and the New Emerging World Order" (1976) discuss this demand. I. W. Zartman, "Europe and Africa: Decolonization i or Dependency" (1976) in a highly controversial article argues that decoloni- zation is a slow process, but a process that is making important progress. African countries are not trapped in a permanent state of dependency; they are working their way out. The Africa Pol i cies of European, Ameri can and Asian States For most of the period since African states gained their independence, countries such as the United States and the Soviet Union have not been partic- ularly active in the development of Africa foreign policies. Britain, France and Belgium -- the ex-colonial powers -- were thought to be the states with the greatest interest in the continent and were, therefore, the states with well- developed Africa policies. The cold war encountered Africa only in a peripheral way. But have times now changed? Viet Nam is over and the Americans are seek- ing new outlets for their energies. The Portuguese have given up their wars in Angola and Mozambique and U.D.I. in Rhodesia is floundering; all of southern Africa is in a state of change. There has been a sudden realization in the U.S.A. that African minerals are important to her economy. And, it appears that the Soviets and their allies have become more interested in African affairs. Now we find many states developing policies for Africa. The United States: Recent comprehensive works on U.S. Africa pol icy in- clude four books: Frederick S. Arkhurst, ed., U.S. Policy toward Africa (1975); Edward W. Chester, Clash of Titans: Africa and U.S. Foreign Policy (1973); Russel 1 Warren Howe, Along the Afric Shore: An Historic Review of Two Centuries of US - African Relations (1975); and P. Will iarn Yarborough, Trial in Africa: The Failure of U.S. Policy (1976). Strong attacks are made on U.S. policy either because it is too weak and is allowing the Soviets to dominate the continent or because it is too supportive of American commercial interests and thus is involved in American domination of the continent. See Stewart Smith, U.S. Neocolonialism in Africa (1975) and M. Gurtov, "Kennedy and Africa" (1974) for expressions of the latter view. American policy is bitterly attacked by the Nigerian writer Chinweizu in his The West and the Rest of Us (1975). Relations between the U.S. and specific African states are considered by a number of scholars. The bulk of such attention has centered on American policy toward the Republic of South Africa. American investments in that state are considered to be supportive of apartheid in Dean McHenry, United States Firms in South Africa I (1975); Ruth First, Jonathan Steele and Christabel Gurney, The South Africa Con- nection: Western Investment in Apartheid (1973); and Ann Seidnan and Neva Seid- man, South Africa and U.S. Mu1 tinational Corporations (1976). Kissinger's suggested "tilt" in favor of the white populations of southern Africa is analyzed in M. A. El-Khawas and 8. Cohen, eds., The Kissinger Study of Southern Africa: National Security Study Memorandum 39 (1976). This contains a copy of that famous memo as well as analysis of the Nixon/Ford southern Africa policies. Anthony Lake, The 'Tar-Baby' Option: American Policy towards Southern Rhodesia (1976) is an equally important analysis. Two other studies of bilateral relations are highly critical of U.S. policy. Michael Bowen et a1 , Passinq by: The United States and Genocide in Burundi, 1972 (1973) argues that a d+fferent U.S. stand on domestic events in Burundi might have reduced violence there. Stephen R. Weissman, American Foreign Policy in the Congo, 1960-1964 (1974) links the class origins of American pol icy makers to the type of policy that emerges. The U.S. involvement in the Angolan Civil War has been subjected to much study, partly because that involvement was ill-advised and a failure but partly because it marked the beginning of a new era in U.S. policy, an era of more active par- ticipation in Africa. Colin Legum and Tony Hodges, After Angola: The War over Southern Africa (1976); Hodges, "The Struggle for Angola: How the World Powers Entered a War in Africa" (1976); and Legum, "The Soviet Union, China and the West in Southern Africa" (1976) analyze the compl icated interplay of American, Soviet, Chinese and South African interests in the Angolan War. The U.S. involvement is further analyzed in Ernest Harsch and Tony Thomas, Angola: The Hidden History of Washington's War (1976) ; M. A. El-Khawas, "American Invol vement in Portuguese Africa: The Legacy of the Nixon Years" (1975); and J. A. Marcum, "Lessons of Angola" (1976). A controversial best-seller, John Stockwell, In Search of Enemies : A CIA Story (1978), is a discussion by one of the participants of the C. I .A. role in the American involvement in Angola. The Assistant Secretary of State for African Affairs at that time was Nathaniel Davis. He presents his insights in "The Angola Decision: A Personal Memi r" (1978). M. A. El-Khawas and F. A. Kornegay, eds., American-Southern African Relations : Bi bl iographic Essays (1975) provides further references on this important aspect of foreign pol icy. American foreign policy is often described as being highly influenced by ethnic groups, as for example with respect to Israel. The biggest ethnic group in the country is its black population, yet until recently this group has played only a minor role as an influence on policy-making. Three works describe and attempt to explain recent changes in that role: M. D. Morris, "Black Americans and the Foreign Pol icy Process: The Case of Africa" (1972); Abdul Aziz Said, ed., Ethnici ty and U.S. Foreign Policy (1977); and R. Wilkins, "What Africa Means to Blacks" (1974). - The USSR: Have the Soviets decided to make major investments of their time and energy in Africa? Do they wish to dominate the area and move it into their sphere of interest? Do they wish to convert Africa to Communism? Or do they see Africa as an opportunity to cause great disarray in the western bloc at a low cost to themselves? Or are they simply a benevolent people who are willing to offer their assistance without strings or ulterior motives to those in need? Such questions, written perhaps in a more sophisticated manner, underlie much of the analysis and description of Soviet policy for Africa. Edward Wilson, Russia and Black Africa before World War 11 (1973) presents clear evidence that Russian and Soviet interest in the continent has existed for many years. The most complete analysis for the present era is Christopher Stevens, The Soviet Union and Black Africa (1976). Stevens discusses political, economic and military relations between 1953 and 1972. He gives special attention to bilateral relations with Guinea, Mali, Kenya, Ghana and Nigeria. For the Soviet view, refer to I. D. Ovsgany, A Study of Soviet Foreign Policy (1975), especially Chapter 111, "The Soviet Union and the Developing States." A distinctly different view, that of a Soviet plot to dominate Africa, is presented in Jan A. du Plessis, "The Soviet Union's Foreign Policy towards Africa" (1974); A. Z. Rubinstein, "The Soviet Union's Imperial Game in Africa" (1977) ; and Walter F. Hahn and Alvin J. Cottrell, Soviet Shadow over Africa (1976). The first two items appear in South African publications; South Africa stresses the comnunist threat to Africa in an effort to maintai n western support for South African domestic and international policies. This argument is vividly stated in G. Poser, "Soviet Sea Power, Southern Africa and World Equil ibrium" (1976). As in the case of the U.S.A., the Angolan Civil War marks an apparent change in Soviet policy. C. Stevens, "The Soviet Union and Angola" (1976) considers Soviet participation in the Angolan War as a benchmark in the history of Soviet African policy. For further analysis see Legurn (1976), Hodges (1976); and Legum and Hodges (1976). William E. Griffith, "Soviet Policy in Africa and Latin America: The Cuban Connection" (1975) argues that Soviet success in Angola may suggest further Soviet successes in southern Africa, but it does not suggest overall success in third world ventures for them. Nigerian-Soviet relations have received attention, especial ly by Nigerian authors: 0. Aluko, "Nigeria and the Superpowers" (1976); 0. J. 6. Ojo, "Nigeria- Soviet Relations" (1976); 0. Igho Natufe, "Nigeria and Soviet Attitudes to African Military Regimes, 1965-1970" (1976) ; and Ogunbadejo (1976). In his most recent essay, " Ideology and Pragmatism: The Soviet Role in Nigeria, 1960-1977," (1 978) Ogunbadejo describes pos t-Stal i nist Soviet pol icy as "pragmatic" as opposed to its previous doctrinaire ri gi di ty. It was this pragmatic character that opened the way for Soviet involvement in the Nigerian civil war. Other analyses of Soviet relations with particular African states include H. Malcolm Kerr, "Soviet Influence in Egypt, 1967-73" (1976); B. Nimer, "The Congo in Soviet Policy" (1973); and C. Stevens, "In Search of the Economic Kingdom: The Development of Economic Relations between Ghana and the U.S.S.R." ('974). A1 though most of the 1 i terature is concerned with Soviet political re? ztions, there are additional studies of economic relations. Warren Weinstein, ed., Chinese and Soviet Aid to Africa (1975) and U.S., Central Intelligence Agency, Communist Aid to Less Developed Countries of the Free World (1976) present useful data and comparative analyses. The broader view of Soviet economic policies can be found in several of the essays in Roger E. Kanet and Donna Bahry, eds., Soviet Economic and Pol i tical Relations with the Developing World (1975). Most of the references ment;oned above conclude that the Soviet Union is be- d having like any other great world power in its African policy. For the most recent analyses see the articles by D. E. Albright and Colin Legum in the January 1978 issue of Problems of Communism. The Albright essay, "Soviet Pol icy," describes the "priorities, general approach, objectives and operating style that have shaped Soviet pol icy in the recent period. " Legum, "The African Environment" analyzes changes in African attitudes toward the U.S.S.R. in recent years. The People's Republic of China: As suggested by Robert Legvold, "Soviet and Chinese Influence in Africa" (1976) there is at least as much competition between the Soviets and the Chinese as between the Soviets and the Americans. Indeed, in recent years there has been a marked correlation between American and Chinese goals and tactics in offsetting the growth of Soviet influence in Africa. George T. Yu, "China's Impact" (1978) "examines the nature of Sino-Soviet rivalry on the continent and its imp1 ications for Soviet-African relations. " Also relevant is George Ginsburgs, "The Soviet View of Chinese Influence in Africa and Latin America" I (1976). There are several comprehensive studies of China's pol icy. Among these are Alan Hutchison, China's African Rev01 ution (1975), which claims that China's goal is not power or the export of rev01 ution; it is simply a desire for friend- ship. Alaba Ogunsanwo, China's Pol icy in Africa, 1956-1971 (1974) argues that China's Africa policy is a product of her competition with the U.S.A. and the U.S.S.R. She wishes to further international strategic interests in Africa. The variety of apparent contradictions in Chinese policy are made more coherent in Bruce D. Larkin, China and Africa, 1949-1970 (1971 ). Two briefer general views are presented in M. A. El-Khawas, "The Development of China's Foreign Pol icy toward Africa, 1955-1 972" (1973) and Po-t'ang Yeh, "Peipi ng's Pol icy towards Africa as Viewed from the Independence of Guinea-Bissau and Mozambique" (1974). Although China has formal and informal relatiqnships with many African states, her attention has focused on Tanzania. George T. Yu, China's African Policy: A Study of Tanzania (1975) is the most complete study of this unusually firm bilateral relationship. The major symbol of this friendship, the important Tanzara Railroad between the Tanzanian coast and Zarnbia,is considered in Richard Hall, The Great Uhuru Rai lway: Chi na ' s Showpiece in Africa (1 976). A thorough description of Chinese foreign aid projects is available in Wolfgang Bartke, China's Economic Aid (1975). This catalog of Chinese aid includes forty-six country surveys. Other Powers: There is surprisingly 1 i ttle recent pub1 ication in Engl i sh about the Africa policies of either the former colonial powers - Britain, France, Belgium, Portugal and Spain - or of other non-major powers. British economic aid programs in southern Africa are discussed in David Jones, Aid and Development in Southern Africa: British Aid to Botswana, Lesotho and Swaziland (1977) and Kathryn Morton, hid and Dependence: British Aid to Malawi (1975). A useful companion to these is the study by Leon Gordenker, Inter- national Aid and National Decisions : Development Programs in Malawi, Tanzania, and Zambia (1976). The author examines the manner in which aid-gi ving organi zations exert influence on recipient states. W. A. Ajibola, "The British Par1 iament and Forei gn-Pol icy Making: A Case Study of Britain's Policy toward the Nigerian Civil War" (1974) is more a study of the British foreign policy process than it is a study of British Africa policy. K. Maxey, "Labour and the Rhodesian Si tuation" (1976) analyzes Harold Wilson's decision to take only weak action when Rhodesian whites declared independence. Other ex-colonial powers are discussed in E. de Sousa Ferreira, "Portugal and her Former African Colonies : Prospects For a Neo-colonial Relationship" (1975) ; W. R. Pendergast, "French Cultural Relations" (1974) ; and W. Weinstein, "The I Limits of Mi 1 i tary Dependency: The Case of Be1 gian Mil i tary Aid to Burundi, 1961- 1973" (1 975). R. 0. Matthews, "Canada's Relations with Africa" (1975) reviews the history of Canadian pol icy since 1945. Matthews and D. G. Anglin have publ ished several 1 articles in the past ten years analyzing Canadian Africa policies. Brazil, a state with trade ties to Africa as we1 1 as ties as a Portuguese-speaking state and a major recipient of slaves in an earlier period, is thought by some observers to view Africa as a potential area for the expansion of Brazilian influence. Aspects of this are discussed in W. A. Selcher, "Brazilian Relations with Portu- guese Africa in the Context of the Elusive ' Luso-Brazi 1 ian Comnuni ty"' (1976). Selcher points out the difficulty that is caused by Brazil's friendship with South Africa. There is also a growing relationship between Nigeria and tirz?il, but this has as yet not been analyzed in any scholarly work. Other non-colonial powers are considered in R. A. Higgot, "Rhetoric and Reality: Austral ia's African Relations under Labour" (1976) ; Richard Thompson (1976); and Dieter Bielenstein, ed., Perspectives in Afro-German Relations (1975). This essay has reviewed only a small proportion of the publ ished i tems 3 available for the study of African politics. We have limited ourselves to recent publications in the English language. Yet, even with these limitations, certain generalizations can be made. To a large extent, the literature is descriptive and prescriptive. It tells us what things do look like or what they should look 1 i ke. But, very few publ ications are analytical. Too, very few studies are com- parative; the majority of publications are based upon single case studies. There is also a wide variety of subjects that have not received very much consideration. For examples, we know very little about the way in which foreign policies are formulated in African states. And, we have little knowledge about the foreign pol icy attitudes of either the African elites or the masses. Too, there has been only very 1 imi ted research on the 1 inkages between domestic and international politics in Africa. And, there is only a limited amount of publication on. the South Africa policies of African states. Some data on the rhetoric of such policies is easily obtainable, but with the exception of a few studies of the "front-1 ine" states, 1 i ttle has been done on the reality of such policies. These are only a few of the weaknesses and lacunae in the scholarly production on African international relations. But one can clearly see that there remains much research, debate and writing to be done. BIBLIOGRAPHY Abangwu, G. C. "Systems Approach to Regional Integration in West Africa." Journal of Comnon Market Studies, 13, 1/2, 1975, 116-133. - Adebisi, B. "Nigeria's Relations with South Africa, 1960-1975." Africa Quarterly, 16, 3, 1977, 67-89. Adedeji , Adebayo. "Prospects of Regional Economic Co-operation in West Africa. " Journal of Modern African Studies, - 8, 2, July 1970, 213-231. Afesi, Dovi. "The Roots of the Crisis." In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed.) . uT. 1 i tary Invol vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Ajala, Adekunle. Pan Africanism: Evolution, Progress and Prospects. London: Andre Deutsch, 1973. 442p. Ajibola, W. A. "The British Parliament and Foreign Policy Making: A Case Study of Britain's Pol icy towards the Niqerian Civil War." Niaerian ~ournal of Economic and social Studies, 76, 1, March 1974, 1291147, tabls. Also in: "British Parliament anbthe Nigerian Crises: Some Background Notes. " Quarterly Journal of Administration, - 8, 3, Apri 1 1974, 305-323. Akindele, R. A. "The Conduct of Nigeria's Foreign Relations, 1960-1975." International Problems, - 12, 3/4, October 1973, 46-65. Akinsanya, Adeoye. "The Afro-Arab Alliance: Dream or Reality." African Affairs, - 30, October 1976, 511-529. . "The European Common Market and Africa." West African Journal of Sociology and Political Science, 1, 2, January 1976, 147-163. - Akinyerni, A. B. Foreign Policy and Federalism: The Nigerian Experience. Ibadan: Ibadan University Press, 1974. xi + 217p. Akpan , Moses E. African Goals and Diplomatic Strategies in the United Na- tions: An Indepth Analysis of African Diplomacy. North Quincy, Mass Chri s topher, 1976. 165p. Plbright, David E. "Soviet Policy." Problems of Comnunism, 11, 1, January/ February 1978, 20-39, ill. A1 uko, Olajide. "Nigeria and the Superpowers." Millenium: Journal of Inter- national Studies, - 5, 2, Autumn 1976, 127-141. . (ed. ). The Foreign Policies of African States. London: Hodder and Stoughton, 1977. 243p. Andemi cael . Berhanvkun. The OAU and the UN: Re1 ati ons between the Oraani zation of ~frican and the United Nations. New York: Africana publishing Co., 1976. 331p., bibl. Arkhurst, Frederick S. (ed. ). U. S. Pol icy toward Africa. New York: Praeger, 1975. XI1 + 295p., tabls. Arnold. Guv. "Rhodesia: Increasina the Effectiveness of Sa~ctions. In: ~tokke, 01 av and Wi ds trand, car1 (eds. ) . The UN-OAU Conference orsouthern Africa, Vol. 11. Uppsala, 1973, 163-172. Bakri , A. K. "The Economic Factor in African-Arab Re1 ations. " Current Bi bl iog- raphy on African Affairs, - 9, 3, 1976/1977, 213-227. Barber, James. South Africa's Foreign Pol icv, 1945- 1970. London: Oxford University Press, 1973. x + 325p., bib1 . , ill. 1 Barrat, John. "Detente in Southern Africa." World Today, - 31, 3, March 1975, 120-1 30. . "Southern Africa: A South African View." Foreign Affairs, - 55. 1, October 1976, 147-168. Barratt, J. The Angolan Conflict. Braamfontein: South African Institute of International Affairs, 1976. iv + 21p. Bartke, Wolfgang. China's Economic Aid. Translated by Waldtrout Jarke. New York: Africana, 1976. 21 5p. Be1 fig1 io, V. J. "Israeli Foreign Aid Programs to Africa." International Problems, - 15, 314, Fa11 1976, 132-144. Bell, J. Bowyer. "Strategic Implications of the Soviet Presence in Soma1 ia." Orbi s, 19, 2, Sumer 1975, 402-41 1 . Bezboruah, Monoranjan. U.S. Strategy in the Indian Ocean. New York: Praeger, 1977. 288p. Bielenstein, Dieter (ed. ). Perspectives in Afro-German Relations. Bonn: Friedri ch-Ebert-Sti ftung, 1975. 241p. Bissell , Richard E. Apartheid and International Organizations. Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1977. 231p. Bone, Marion. "The Foreign Policy of Zambia." In: Boorston, Ronald P.(ed.). The Other Powers: Studies in the Foreign Klicies of Small States. London, 1973, 121-153. Bowen, Michael, et a1 . Passing by: The United States and Genocide in Burundi, 1972. Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1973. 49p. Bowman, Larry W. "The Subordinate State System of Southern Africa. " International Studies Quarterly, 12, 3, September 1968, 231-261. Also in: David S. McLellan, et al. (ez.). The Theory and Practice of International Relations. Engl ewood Cl i ffs , 1974, 455-466. . Politics in Rhodesia: White Power in an African State. Cambridge, Mass. : Harvard University Press, 1973. xi + 206p. Bozernan, Adda B. Conflict in Africa: Concepts and Realities. Princeton, Pi. J. : Princeton University Press, 1976. xiv + 429p. Brooks, Hugh C. and El-Ayouty, Yassin (eds.). Refugees South of the Sahara: An African Dilemma. Westport: Negro Universities Press, 1970. xviii + 307p., ill., maps. Carter, G. and O'Meara, P. Southern Africa in Crisis. Bloomington, Indiana: Indiana University Press, forthcoming. 3 Cervenka, Zdenek (ed. ) . Land-Locked Countries of Afri ca. Uppsal a : Scandanavian Institute of African Studies, 1973. 368p. . "The Emergence and Significance of the African-Arab Solidarity." Instant Research on Peace and Violence, 4, 2, 1974, 102-109. . "Major Policy Shifts in the Organization of African Unity, 1963-1973." In: Ingham, K. (ed. ) . Forei gn Relations of African States. London, 1974, 32 3- 344. . "Africa and the New International Order." Verfassung and Recht in cbersee, 9, 2, 1976, 187-199. - . The Unfinished Quest for Unity: Africa and the OAU. London: Julian Friedmann, 1978. 256 p., map. and Rogers, Barbara. The Nuclear Axis : Nuclear Col laboration between West Germany and South Africa. London: Julian Friedmann, 1978. 288p., maps. Chartrand, P. E. "The Organization of African Unity and African Refugees: A Pro- gress Report." World Affairs, 137, 4, Spring 1975, 265-285. Chester, Edward W. Clash of Titans: Africa and the United States Foreign Pol icy. Maryknoll, New York: Orbis, 1974. ix + 316p., bibl. Chibwe, E. C. Afro-Arab Relations in the New World Order. London: Julian Friedmann, 1978. 256p. Chinweizu. The West and the Rest of Us. New York: Random House, 1975. 520p. Chukwura, A. 0. "Organi zation of African Unity and African Terri torial and Boundary Problems 1963-1 973. " Niqerian Journal of International Studies, 1, 1, July 1975, 56-81. Coll ins, J. D. "The Clandestine Movement of Groundnuts across the Ni ger-Nigeria Boundary." Canadian Journal of African Studies, 10, 2, 1976, 259-278, tabls. Collins, J. N. "Foreign Conflict Behavior and Domestic Disorder in Africa." In: Mi1 kenfeld, J. (ed. ). Conflict Behavior and Linkage Politics. New ~orc 1973, 251-294. Copson, R. W. "Foreign Policy Conflict among African States 1964-1969." In: McGowan, P. (ed. ). Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Policy ~Gdies, 1, 1973, 189-218. . "African International Pol i tics: Underdevelopment and Confl ict in the Seventies." - Orbis, - 22, 1, Spring 1978, 227-245. Cox, Courtland. "Western Strategy in Southern Africa. " In: Western Mass. As- sociation of Concerned African Scholars (ed. ). U.S.M~ 1 i tary Involvement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Crocker, Chester A. "Mi 1 i tary Dependence: The Colonial Legacy in Africa. " Journal of Modern African Studies, - 12, 2, June 1974, 265-286. . "The African Dimension of Indian Ocean Policy." - Orbis, - 20, 3, Fall 1976, 637-667. Curry, R. L., Jr. and Rothchild, Donald. "On Economic Bargaining between African Governments and Mu1 ti -Nati onal Companies. " Journal of Modern Afri can Studies, 12, 2, 1974, 173-189. - Curtis, Michael and Gi telson, Susan A. Israel in the Third World. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books, Rutgers University, 1976. 410p. Dale, Richard. "President Sir Seretse Khama, Botswana's Forei qn Pol icy, and the Southern African Subordinate State System. " Pl ural societies, - 7; 1 , Spring 1976, 69-87. Davis, Nathaniel. "The Angola Decision of 1975: A Personal Memoir." Foreign Affairs, 57, 1, Fall 1978, 109-124. - Decalo, S. "Africa and the UN Anti-Zionism Resolution: Roots and Causes," Cultures et Dgveloppement, 8, 1, 1976, 89-117. DeLancey, Mark W. Teaching the International Relations of Africa: A Collection of Svl labi . Columbia. S.C. : Institute of International Studies, University d - of South Carolina, 1975. 74p., bibl. . "Current Studies in African International Relations." Africana Journal, 1, 3, 1976, 195-239. . "The International Relations of Southern Africa. " ~en\eve-~fri~ue, 2, 1976, 82-135. . "The Africa Policies of the United States, the Soviet Union and the People's Republic of China." Africa (Rome), 33, 1, March 1978, 97-1 16. Dingeman, James. "Covert Operations in Central and Southern Africa. " In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed. ) . U.S. ~i 1 iGry Invol ve- ment in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Djamson, E .O. The Dynamics of Euro-African Co-operation : Being an Analysis and Exposition of Institutional , Legal and Socio-Economic Aspects of Association/ Co-opera ti on wi th the European Economi c Cornmuni ty . The Hague : Marti nus Ni j ho 1976. xxiii + 370p., bibl. Doro, Marion E. "A Bibliographical Essay on the November 1971 Rhodesian Settlement Proposals." A Current Bibliography on African Affairs, - 6, 4, Fa1 1 1973, 41 1- 430, bibl. Doxey, K. "International Sanctions: A Framework for Analysis with Special Reference to the Uni ted Nations and Southern Africa. " International Orqani zation, - 26, 3, Summer 1972, 527-550. Drucker, P. F. "Mu1 tinationals and Developing Countries : Myths and Real i ties." Foreign Affairs, - 53, 1, October 1974, 121-134. El-Ayouty, Yassi n. Africa and International Organization. Hague: Ni jhoff, 1974. 250p. . (ed.). The Organization of African Unity after Ten Years. New York: Praeger, 1975. xi + 262p. El-Khawas, Mohamed A. "The Development of China's Forei gn Pol icy toward Africa, 1955-1972. " Current Bibliography on African Affai rs, Spring 1973, 129-1 39, tabl . . "Afri can-Arab Sol i dari ty : The Emergence of a New A1 1 iance. " Current Bibliography on African Affairs, 8, 2, 1975, 134-145. . "American Invol vement in Portuguese Africa: The Legacy of the Nixon Years." Ufaharnu, - 6, 1, 1975, 117-130, tabl. and Cohen, Barry (eds. ). The Kissinger Study of Southern Africa: National Securi ty Study Memorandum 39. Westport, Conn . : Lawrence Hi 11 , 1976. 189p. and Kornegay, F. A. , Jr. (eds. ) . American-Southern African Relations : Bi bl i ographi c Essays. Westport, Conn . : Greenwood Press, 1975. 188p. Enloe, Cynthia. "Mercenarization. " In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned Afri can Schol ars (ed. ) . U .S. ~iEtary vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Esedebe, P. 0. "What Is Pan-Africanism?" Journal of African Studies, 4, 2, Summer 1977, 167-1 87. Eze, 0. C. "Prospects for International Protection of Human Rights in Africa." African Review, !, 1, 1974, 79-90. Farer, Tom J. War Clouds on the Horn of Africa: A Crisis f0.r dtente. New York: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1976. 157p. Ferreira, E. de Sousa. "Portugal and her Former African Colonies: Prospects for a Neo-Colonial Relationship." Ufahamu, 5, 3, 1975, 159-170, tabl. Fi rst, Ruth; Steel e, Jonathan ; and Gurney, Chris tabel. The South African Connection : Western Investment in Apartheid. Harrnondsworth : Penguin, 1973. 352p. 4 Gal tung, J. "The Lome Convention and Neo-capi talism." African Review, 6, 1, 1976, 33-42. Gambari , I. A. "Nigeria and the World: A Growing Internal Stability, Wealth, and External Influence." Journal of International Affairs, - 29, 2, Fall Gervasi, Sean. "Breakdown of the U.S. Embargo." In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed.). U.S. ti tar^ Involvement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Gibson, Richard. African Li beration Movements : Contemporary Struggles aqai nst White Minority Rule. London: Oxford University Press, 1972. x + 350p., bib1 . , map, tab1 . Ginsburgs, George. "The Soviet View of Chinese Influence in Africa and Latin America. " In: Rubinstein, A1 vin Z. (ed. ). Soviet and Chinese Infl uence in the ~hirr~orld. York, 1976. Gitelson, S. A. "Can the United Nations be an Effective Catalyst for Regional Integration? The Case of the East African Comnuni ty. " Journal of-~evel op- ing Areas, - 8, 1, October 1973, 65-82. . "Why Do Small States Break Diplomatic Relations with Outside Pcrers? Lessons from the African Experience. " International Studies Quarterly, 18, 4, December 1974, 451-484. - Good, Robert C. U.D. I. : The International Politics of the Rhodesian Rebell ion. London: Faber and Faber, 1973. Princeton : Princeton Universi t.y Press, Gordenker, Leon. International Aid and National Decisions : Development Programs in Malawi, Tanzania, and Zambia. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1976. 190p. Green, R. H. "The LOW' Convention : Updated Dependence or Departure toward Col - lective Self-Reliance?" African Review, - 6, 1, 1976, 43-54. and Seidman, A. Unity or Poverty? The Economics of Pan-Africanism. Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1968. 363p. Griffith, William E. "Soviet Policy in Africa and Latin America: The Cuban Connection." - In: William E. Griffith (ed.) The Soviet Empire: Expansion and ~6tente. Lexington, Mass., 1975, 337-344. Gruhn, I. V. "The LOW' Convention: Inching towards Interdependence." Inter- national Organi zation, - 30, 2, Spring 1976, 241-262. Grundy, Kenneth W. Guerrilla Struggle in Africa. New York: Grossman, 1971. 204p. . "Intermediary Power and Global Dependence: The Case of South Africa." International Studies Quarterly, 20, 4, December 1976, 553-580. Gurtov, M. "Kennedy and Africa." In: Gurtov, M. The United States against the Third World: ~ntinational stnand Intervention. New York, 1974, 41 -81. Hahn, Walter F. and Cottrell , Alvin J. Soviet Shadow over Africa. Miami : Center for Advanced International Studies, University of Miami, 1976. 105p. Hall, Richard. The Hiqh Price of Principles. Kaunda and the White South. Har- mndsworth: Penguin, 1973. 286p. . The Great Uhuru Railway: China's Showpiece in Africa. London: Gollancz, 1976. 208p., ill. I Hal let, Robin. "The South African Intervention in Angola, 1975-1976." African Affairs, - 77, 308, July 1978, 347-386. Harsch: Ernest and Thomas, Tony. Angola: The Hidden History of Washington's a. New York: Path, 1976. Hartwig, Gerald W. and O'Barr, William M. The Student Africanist's Handbook: A Guide to Resources. New York: John Wiley, 1974. 152p. Hassan, A. D. "Big Power Rivalry in Indian Ocean - A Tanzanian View." Africa Quarterly, - 15, 3, 1976, 80-86. Henderson, Mil 1 ie. "Independent Botswana: A Re-appraisal of Foreign Pol icy I Options." African Affairs, 73, January 1974, 37-49. Hevener, Natal ie K. "The 1971 South-West African Opinion - A New International Juridical Philosophy. " International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 24, October 1975, 791-810. Higgot, R. A. "Rhetoric and Reality: Australia's African Relations under Labour." Journal of Comnonweal th and Comparative Politics, 14, 2, July 1976, 158-176. I - Hi rschmann , D. "Southern Africa : ~itente?" Journal of Modern African Studies, I - 14, 1, March 1976, 107-126. Hodges, Tony. "The Struggle for Angola: How the World Powers Entered a War in Africa." Round Table, 262, April 1976, 173-184. Holborn, Louise W. Refugees: A Problem of Our Time. Metuchen, New Jersey: Scarecrow Press, 1975. 1543p., ill. Hoover, A1 ice. "Pan-Africanism: A Selective Bi bl iography. " A Current Bi bl iog- raphy on African Affairs, - 4, 1, January 1971, 10-24. Howe, Russell Warren. Along the Afric Shore: An Historic Review of Two Centuries of US-African Relations. New York: Barnes and Noble, 1975. 197p. Hutchinson, Alan. China's African Revolution. London: Hutchinson, 1975. xiii + 313p., ill., maps. Hveem, H. and Hol the, 0. K. "European Economic Comnuni ty and the Third World. " Instant Research on Peace and Violence, 2, 1972, 73-85. Idang, G. J. Nigeria: Internal Politics and Foreign Pol icy, 1960-1966. Ibadan: University Press, 1973. ix + 171p. Ingham, K. (ed. ). Forei gn Relations of Afri can States. London : Butterworths, 1974. xii + 344p., figs, maps, tabls. Ismael, Tareq Y. The United Arab Republ ic in Africa: Egypt's Pol icy under Nasser. Evanston: Northwestern University Press, 1971. 258p. Jones, David. Aid and Development in Southern Africa: British Aid to Botswana, Lesotho, and Swazi land. London: Croorn Helm, 1977. 31 3p. Jukes, Geoffrey. The Indian Ocean in Soviet Naval Pol icy. London: International Institute for Strategic Studies, 1972. 30p. (Adel phi Paper, 87. ) Karnanu, Onyeonow S. "Secession and the Right to Self-Detemination: An Organi- zation of African Unity Dilemma." Journal of Modern African Studies, z, 3, 1974, 355-376. Kanet, Roger E. and Bahry, Donna (eds. ). Soviet Economic and Political Relations with the Developing World. New York: Praeger, 1975. 242p. Kapil, R. L. "On the Conflict Potential of Inherited Boundaries in Africa." World Politics, - 18, 4, July 1966, 656-673. Kapungu, Leonard T. The United Nations and Economic Sanctions against Rhodesia. Lexington, Massachusetts: Lexington Books, 1973. 11 5p., ill. Kerr, Malcolm H. "Soviet Influence in Egypt, 1967-73." In: Rubinstein, Alvin Z. (ed. ). Soviet and Chinese Influence in the ~hird~orld. York, 1975. Khapoya, Vincent B. "Determinants of Afri can Support for African Liberation Movements : A Comparative Analysis. " Journal of African Studies, 3, 4, Winter 1976, 469-489, tab1 s . Kirk-Greene, A. H. M. "Dip1omac.y and Diplomats: The Formation of Foreign Service Cadresin Black ~frica." in: lngham, K.(ed.). Foreign Relations of African States. London, 1974, 279322. figs., tabls. Klare, Michael and Prokosch, Erik. "Evading the Arms Embargo: How the U.S. Arms South Africa and Rhodesia." In: Western Mass. Association of Con- cerned African Scholars (ed. ). U.S. Mil i tary Invol vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Kochan, Ran; Gitelson, Susan A.; and Dubek, Ephriam. "Black African UN Voting Behavior on the Middle East Conflict 1967-1972. " Jerusalem Journal of International Relations, 1, 2, 1976, 21-52. Lake, Anthony. The Tar-Baby Option : American Pol icy toward Southern Rhodesia. New York: Columbia University Press for the Carnegie Endowment for Inter- national Peace, 1976. 316p. Langdon, S. "The Political Economy of Dependence: Note toward Analysis of Mu1 ti national Corporations in Kenya. " Journal of East African Research and Development, - 4, 2, 1974, 123-159. Lapchick, Richard Edward. The Politics of Race and International Sport: The Case of South Africa. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press, 1975. 268p. Larkin, Bruce D. China and Africa, 1949-1970: The Foreign Pol icy of the People's Republ ic of China. Berkeley: Uni versi ty of Cal ifornia Press, 1971. 268p. Legum, Col in. Pan-Africanism: A Short Pol i ti cal Guide . New York : Praeger, 1962. 296p., maps. Revised edition, 1965. 326p. . (ed.). Africa Contemporary Record. London: Africa Research Ltd., 1974/ 1975, 1100p. New York: Africana Pub1 ishing Co., 1974/1975. . "The Organization of African Unity: Success or Fai 1 ure?" International Affairs, 51, 2, April 1975, 208-219. - 0 . "Southern Africa: The Politics of Detente." Yearbook of World Affairs, 30, 1976, 14-29. - . "The Soviet Union, China and the West in Southern Africa." Foreiqn Affairs, 54, 4, July 1976, 745-762, map. - . "Vorster's Gamble for Africa. New York: Africana, 1976. 90p. . "The African Environment." Problems of Communism, 27, 1, January/ - February 1978, 1-19, 1, and Hodges, Tony. After Angola: The liar over Southern Africa. London: Rex Coll ings, 1976. New York: Africana, 1976. 85p. Legvold, Robert. "Soviet and Chinese Influence in Africa." In: Rubinstein, Alvin Z. (ed.). Soviet and Chinese Influence in the ~hGd New York, 1975. Libby, R. T. "External Co-optation of a Less Developed Country's Policy Making: The Case of Ghana, 1969-1972." World Politics, 29, 1, October 1976, 67-89. - Makgetla, Neva Seidman and Seidman, Ann. "U.S. Transnational Corporations' In- vol vement in South Africa's Military-Industrial Complex." In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed.). ~.s~ilitary vol vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Marcum, John A. "Lessons of Angola." Foreign Affairs, 54, 3, April 1976, 407-425. - Marks, T. A. "Spanish Sahara-Background to Conflict." African Affairs, 75, 298, - January 1976, 3-1 3, map. Matthews, R. 0. "Canada's Relations with Africa." International Journal, 30, 3, Summer 1975, 536-568. Maxey, K. "Labour and the Rhodesian Situation." African Affairs, 299, April 1976, 152-162. Maya1 1, James. "Oi 1 and Nigerian Foreign Pol icy." African Affairs, 75, 300, - July 1976, 31 7-330. Mazrui, A. A. "Black Africa and the Arabs." Foreign Affairs, 53, 4, July 1975, - 725-742. . Africa's International Relations : The Diplomacy of Dependency and Change. Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1977. London: Heinemann, 1977. 310p. and Patel, Hasu 1. (eds. ). Africa in World Affairs: The Next Thirty Years. New York: Third Press, 1973. xii + 265p. McGowan, P. J. and Gottwald, K. P. "Small State Foreign Policies: A Comparative Study of Participation, Conflict, and Political and Economic Dependence in Black Africa." International Studies Quarterly, - 19, 4, December 1975, 469- 500. McHenry, Dean. United States Firms in South Africa: Study Project on External Investment in South Africa and Namibia. 61 oorni nqton , Indiana : African Studies Program, Indiana University, 1975. 4op.; tab1 s. ~ McMaster, Carolyn, Malawi: Foreign Policy and Development. London: Julian Friedmann, 1975. New York: St. Martins Press, 1975. 270p., maps. Meyers, B. David. "Intraregional Conflict Management by the OAU." International Organization, - 28, 3, Summer 1974, 345-373. . "The Organization of African Unity: An Annotated Bibliography." Pfricana Journal, - 5, 4, Winter 1974, 308-321. Miller, J. C. "African-Israel : Relations Impact on Continental Unity. " Middle East Journal, - 29, 4, Autumn 1979, 393-408. Minter, Wi 11 iarn. "Major Themes in Mozambican Foreign Relations, 1975-1977. " Issue, 8, 1, Spring 1978, 43-49. - 4 Morris, M. D. "Black Americans and the Foreign Policy Process: The Case of Africa." Western Pol i tical Quarterly, 2, 3, September 1972, 451-463. Morrison, D. H., et al. Black Africa: A Comparative Handbook. New York: Free Press, 1972. xxviii + 483p., tabls. Morton, Kathryn. Aid and Dependence: British Aid to Malawi. London: Croorn Helm, 1975. 189p., map, tabls. Mtshal i , B. Vul indel a. Rhodesia: Background to Conflict. New York: Hawthorn Books, 1967. 255p. . "The Zambian Foreign Service, 1964-1972." African Review, - 5, 3, 1975, 303- 31 6, tabl s. Mubako, S. V. "The Rhodesian Border Blockade of 1973 and the African Liberation Struggle. " Journal of Comnonweal th and Comparative Pol i tics, - 12, 3, November 1974. 297-312. "I Mugomba, Agrippah T. "The Rise and Fall of 'Pax Suid-Afrika' : A Historical Analysis of South Africa's Black African Foreign Pol icy." Kenya Historical "The Multinationals and Africa." Review of African Political Economy, April 1975, - 1 1-109, tab?, Mytel ka, Lynn K 'A Genealogy of Francophone West and Equatori a1 - African - Regional 7 Organizations. " Journal of Modern African Studil bi bl . , tabl . es, 12, 2, 1974, 297-320, 1 Naqel , Ronald K. doc urn en tar.^ Resources of the Organization of African Uni ty - on its First ~uintade Current ~i African Affai rs , 3, 11/12, Novernber/December 1970, 19-24. Natufe, 0. Igho. "Nigeria and Soviet Attitudes to African Military Regimes, 1965-1970." Survey, 22, 1 , Winter 1976, 93-1 11. Ndongko, W. A. "Trade and Development,Aspects of the Central African Customs and Economic Union. " Cul tures et Development, 1, 2, 1975, 337-355, tab! s. / . "From Economic Domination to Association: Africa in the EEC." Presence Africaine, 99/103, 1976, 181-195. Nehwati , Francis. "Economic Sanctions against Rhodesia." In: Stokke, Olav and and Widstrand, Carl (eds. ). The UN-OAU Conference on Suthern Africa, Vol. 11. Uppsala, 1973, 151-161, tabls. Nirner, B. "The Congo in Soviet Policy." Survey, 19, 1, Winter 1973, 184-210. Nixson, F. I. Economic Integration and Industrial Location: An East African Case Study. London: Longman, 1973. 181p., bibl . , map. Nkrumah, Kwame. Africa Must Unite. New York: Praeger, 1963. xvii + 229p. London: Hei nemann, 1963. New York: International , 1970. Nolutshungu, Sam C. South Africa in Africa: A Study of Ideology and Foreign Policy. New York: Africana Publishing Co., 1975. viii + 329p., bibl., maps. Nworah, D. "The Integration of the Comnission for Technical Co-operation in Africa with the Organization of African Unity: The Process of the Merger and the Problems of Institutional Rivalry and Complementarity. " African Review, - 6, 1, 1976, 55-67. Obozuwa, A. Ukiornogbe. The Namibian Question: Legal and Pol i tical Aspects. Benin City: Ethiope Publishing Co., 1973. xviii + 256p. Ogunbadejo, Oye. "Nigeria and the Great Powers: The Impact of the Civil War on Nigerian Foreign Relations. " African Affairs, 75, 298, January 1976, 14-32. . "Ideology and Pragmatism: The Soviet Role in Nigeria, 1960-1977." Orbis 21, 4, Winter 1978, 803-830. - Ogunsanwo, A1 aba. China ' s Pol i cy in Afri cay 1958-1 971 . New York : Cambri dge University Press, 1974. 336p., bibl . Ojo, Olatunde J. B. "Nigeria-Soviet Relations: Retrospect and Prospect." African Studies Review, 19, 3, December 1976, 43-63. Okumu, J. J. "Some Thoughts on Kenya's Foreign Policy." African Review, - 3, 2, June 1973, 263-290. O'Meara, Patrick. Rhodesia: Racial Conflict or Co-existence. Ithaca, New York: Cornel 1 Uni versi ty Press, 1975. 21 7p. Ovsgany, I. D. et al. A Study of Soviet Foreiqn Policy. Translated by David Skvi rs ky. Moscow: Progress, 1975. 379p. '\ Pendergast, W. R. "French Cultural Relations." Chronique de Pol i tique Etranqere, 27, 3, May 1974, 339-356. - Pettman, Jan. Zambia: Security and Conflict. London: Julian Friedmann, 1974. 292 p., bibl., maps. Plessis, Jan A. du. "The Soviet Union's Foreign Policy towards Africa." Bulletin of the Africa Institute of South Africa, 12, 3, 1974, 105-115. - Polhemus, James H. "The Provisional Secretariat of the O.A.U., 1963-1964. " Journal of Modern African Studies, - 12, 2, 1974, 287-295. Zoser, G. "Soviet Sea Power, Southern Africa and World Equilibrium." South Africa International, - 7, 2, October 1976, 73-80. Prados, John. "Sealanes, Western Strategy and Southern Africa. " In: Wes te :n Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed. ). U.S. ~il Involvement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Prain, Ronald. "Metals and Africa: Economic Power in an International Setting. " African Affairs, - 77, 307, April 1978, 236-246. Pratt, R. C. "Foreign Policy Issues and the Emergence of Social ism in Tanzania, 1961-1 968. " International Journal, - 30, 3, Summer 1975, 445-460. Renninger, J. P. "After the Seventh Special (UN) General Assembly Session: Africa and the New Emerging Worl d order.. " ~fri Studies ~evi ," - 19, 2, September 1976, 35-48. Robertson, Ian. (ed.). Race and Politics in South Africa. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction, 1977. Rood, Lesl ie L. "Foreign Investment in African Development." Journal of African Studies, - 5, 1, Spring 1978, 18-33. Rubin, Neville. "Africa and Refugees." African Affairs, - 73, 292, July 1974, 290-311, tabls. Rubinstein, A. Z. "The Soviet Union's Imperial Game in Africa." Optima, - 26, 3, 1977, 114-125, ill., map. Sagay, I. The Legal Aspects of the Namibian Dispute. Ile-Ife: University of Ife Press, 1975. 464p. Said, Abdul Aziz (ed.). Ethnicity and U.S. Foreign Policy. New York: Praeger, 1978. 180p. Samuels, Michael A. (ed.). The Horn of Africa. New Brunswick, N. J. : Trans- action, 1978. 96p. Saxena, S. C. "Namibia and the United Nations." Indian Journal of Politics, - 36, 3, July-September 1975, 274-296. Schwab, Peter. "Cold War on the Horn of Africa." African Affairs, 11, 306, - January 1978, 6-21 . Seidman, Ann and Seidman, Neva. South Africa and U.S. Multinational Corporations. Westport, Conn. : Lawrence Hill, 1978. xxii + 251p., maps, tabls. Selcher, W. A. "Brazilian Relations with Portuguese Africa in the Context of the Elusive ' Luso-Brazil ian Communi ty. "' Journal of Interameri can Studies and World Affairs, - 18, 1, February 1976, 25-58. Sharkansky, I. and Dresang, D. L. "International Assistance: Its Variety, Co- ordination, and Impact among Public Corporations in Kenya and the East African Community. " International Organization, 28, 2, Spring 1974, 207-231. - Shaw, Timothy M. "African States and International Stratification: The Adaptive Foreign Policy of Tanzania." In: Ingham, K. (ed.). Foreign Relations of African States. London, 1974, 213-236, figs- . "Southern Africa: Cooperation and Conflict in an International Sub - System." Journal of Modern African Studies, 12, 4, 1974, 633-655. - . "Discontinuities and Inequalities in African International Politics." International Journal, - 30, 3, Summer 1975, 369-390. . "The Pol itical Economy of African International Relations." Issue, 5, 4, Winter 1975, 29-38. - . Dependence and Underdevelopment: The Development and Foreign Policies of Zambia. Athens: Ohio University, 1976. vii + 60p., bibl., maps. . "The Foreign Pol icy of Zambia: Ideology and Interests. " Journal of Modern African Studies, - 14, 1, March 1976, 79-105. . the Foreign Policy System of Zambia." African Studies Review, 19, 1, April 1976, 31-63. . "Kenya and South Africa: ' Subimperial ist States. "I -- 21, 2, ~umrner 1977, 375-394. and Grieve, M. J. "The Pol i tical Economy of Resources: Africa's Future i n the Gl obal Envi ronment. " Journal of Modern African Studies, - 16, 1 , March 1978, 1-32. and Heard. Kenneth A. (eds. ). Coo~eration and Conflict in Southern Africa: '- Papers on a ~e~ional washi ngton : Uni versi ty Press of America, 1976. 479p. Shepherd, George W. , Jr. Anti-Apartheid: Transnational Conflict and Western Pol icy in the Liberation of South Africa. Westport, Conn. : Greenwood, 1977. 246p. Sierra, Sergio. "Raci sm and Fascism in the Southern Atlantic. " African Comnunist, 74, 1978, 100-109. Skinner, E. P. "African States and Israel : Uneasy Relations in a World of Crises." Journal of African Studies, 2, 1, Spring 1975, 1-23. Sklar, Richard L. Corporzte Power in an African State: The Political Impact of Mu1 tinational Mining Companies in Zambia. Berkeley: University of Cal i forni a Press, 1975. 245p. Skurnik, W. A. E. Sub-Saharan Africa: A Guide to Information Services. Detroit: Gale Research Co., 1977. x + 130p. Slonim, Solomon. South West Africa and the United Nations: An International Mandate in Dispute. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press, 1973. 409p., bibl., map. Smith, Shei la M. "Economic Dependence and Economic Empi ricism in Black Africa. " Journal of Modern African Studies, 15, 1, March 1977, 116-118. Smith, Stewart. United States Neocolonialism in Africa. New York: International Publishers, 1974. 270p. Sohn, Loui s B. African Regional Organi zati on : Hi story, Li terature and 3asi c Documents. Dobbs Ferry, New York: Oceana, 1971. 4 volumes. Stephen, M. "Natural Justice at the United Nations: The Rhodesian Case." American Journal of International Law, - 67, 3, July 1973, 479-490. Stephenson, G. V. "The Impact of International Economic Sanctions on the Internal Viabi 1 i ty of Rhodesia. " Geographical Review, 3, July 1975, 377-389, maps, tabl s . Stevens, Christopher. "In Search of the Economic Kingdom: The Development of ~conomic ~ei between Ghana and the U.S.S.R. " Journal of evel loping Areas, 9, 1 , October 1974, 3-26, tabl s. . "The Soviet Union and Angola." African Affairs, - 75, 299, April 1976, 137-151. . The Soviet Union and Black Africa. New York: Holmes and Meier, 1976. 276p. , tabl s . Stevens, Richard P. "The 1972 Addis Ababa Agreement and the Sudan's Afro-Arab Policy." Journal of Modern African Studies, - 14, 2, 1976, 247-274. Stockholm International Peace Research Ins ti tute. Southern Africa: The Escalation of a Conflic,. New York: Praeger, 1976. 235p. Stockwell, John. In Search of Enemies: A CIA Story. New York: Norton, 1978. 288p. Sudarkasa, N. "Commercial Migration in West Africa, with Special Reference to the Yoruba in Ghana." African Urban Notes, Ser. 0, 1, Winter 1974/1975, 61-103, bibl. Sylvester, Robert. "Observation of the U.S. Arms Embargo." In: Western F'ass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed. ) . U.S. ~3i Invol vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. Tandon, Yashpal. "An Analysis of the Foreign Policy of African States: A Case Study of Uganda." In: Ingham, K. (ed.). Foreign Relations of African States. London, 1974, 191-21 1. . (ed). Readings in African Internztional Relations. Nairobi : East African ~iterature 1972. Vol. I, x + 380p. 1974. Vol. 11, 270p. Thompson, Richard. Retreat from Apartheid: New Zealand's Sporting Contacts wi th South Africa. Wellington, N. Z.: Oxford University Press, 1976. vii + 102p. Tomlin, B. W. and Buhlman, M. A. "Relative Status and Foreign Policy: Status Partioning and the Analysis of Relations in Black Africa." Journal of Conflict Resolution, - 21, 2, June 1977, 187-216, tabls. Touval , Saadia. The Boundary Pol i tics of Independent Africa. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1972. 334p. Uni ted States. Central Intel 1 i gence Agency. Cornrnuni s t Aid to the Less Developed Countries of the Free World. Washington: C.I.A., 1976. 33p. Vengroff, R. "Neo-colonialism and Pol icy Outputs in Africa." Comparative Political Studies, - 8, 2, July 1975, 234-250. . "Instability and Foreign Policy Behavior: Black Africa in the UN." American Journal of Political Science, - 20, 3, August 1976, 425-438. Villiers, D. P. de. "Southern Africa and the Future." South Africa International, 5, 4, April 1975, 189-197. - jlallensteen, P. "Dealing with the Devil. Five African States and South Africa." Instant Research on Peace and Violence, 3, 1971, 85-99. Wal lers te in, Imanuel . "Dependence in an Interdependent World: The Limi ted Possi bil i ties of Transformation within the Capi tal ist World Economy. " African Studies Review, 17, 1, April 1974, 1-26. - Walters, Ronald. "U.S. Po1ic.y and Nuclear Proliferation in S. Africa." In: Western Mass. ~ssociation Concerned African Scholars (ed,). ~.~r~ili Invol vement in Southern Afri ca. Boston, 1978. Weinstein, Warren (ed. ). Chinese and Soviet Aid to Africa. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1975. xxi + 290p. . "The Limits of Military Dependency: The Case of Be1 gian Military Aid to Burundi, 1961-1973," Journal of African Studies, 2, 3, Fall 1975, 419- - 431, tabls. Weissman, Stephen R. American Foreign Pol icy in the Congo, 1960-1964. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1974. 325p. Were, Gideon S. A History of South Africa. New York: Africana Publishing Co., 1974. xvi + 198p.,53bl., III- Western Massachusetts Association of Concerned African Schol ars , Edi torial Col- lective. "The Crisis in Southern Africa." In: Western Mass. Association of Concerned African Scholars (ed. ). U.S. MT~ Invol vement in Southern Africa. Boston, 1978. . U.S. Military Involvement in Southern Africa. Boston: South End, 1978. Wi dstrand, Carl . G. (ed. ) . African Boundary Problems. Uppsala: Scandanavi an Institute of African Studies, 1969. New York: Africana Pub1 ishing Company, . (ed. ). Mu1 tinational Firms in Africa. Uppsala: Scandanavian Institute of African Studies, 1975. New York: Africana, 1976. 425p., tabls. Wilkins, R. "What Africa Means to Blacks." Foreign Policy, 15, Sumner 1974, 130-142. Wi 11 iarns, Michael and Parsonage, Michael. "Britain and Rhodesia: The Economic Background to Sanctions. " World Today, 3, 9, September 1973, 379-388, tab1 s. Wilmer, S. "Ten Years of Vain Negociations." Instant Research on Peace and Violence, 2, 1972, 67-72. A1 so in: East Africa Journal, 9, 2, February 1972, 26-29. Wilson, Edward. Russia and Black Africa before World War 11. New York: Holmes and Meier, 1973. 397~. Wolfers, M. Politics in the OAU. London: Methuen, 1976. x + 229p. 1 Yarborough, William P. Trial in Africa: The Failure of U.S. Policy. Washington, D. C.: Heritage Foundation, 1976. 86p. Yeh, Po-t'ang. "Peiping's Policy towards Africa as Viewed from the Independence of Guinea-Bissau and Mozambique." Issues and Studies, 10, 15, December 1974, 2-12. Yu, G. T. China's Africa Policy: A Study of Tanzania. New York: Praeger, 1975. xxi + 200p., bibl., tabls. . "China's Impact." Problems of Communism, - 27, 1, JanuarylFebruary 1978, 40-50, ill., tabls. Zacklin, Ralph. The United Nations and Rhodesia: A Study in International Law. New York: Praeger, 1974. 202p. Zart .man, I. William. "Africa as a Subordinate Sta ~elations. International Organization, 21, Also in: Doro, M. E. and Stultz, N. M. (as Enql ewood Cl i ffs , New Jersey, 1970, 324-341. Mendl ovi tz, S. ti. (eds. ) . ~egi Pol i ti cs 1973, 384-397. te System in International 3, Sumer 1967, 545-554. . Governina in Black Africa. d Also in: Falk, R. A. and and World Order. San Francisco, . "Africa." In: James N. Rosenau, K. W. Thompson and G. Boyd (eds.). Worl d Pol i tics- New York, 1976, 569-594. . "Europe and Africa: Decolonization or Dependency?" Foreign Affairs, 54, 2, January 1976, 325-343. - DEPENDENCE OR I NTERDEPENDENCE : AFRICA IN THE GLOBAL POLITICAL ECONOMY Timothy M. Shaw, Dal housie University M. Catharine Newbury, Wesleyan Uni versi ty The international relations and foreign pol icies of African states are becoming more complex and controversial. Their complexity relates to increases in the number of actors and issues in contemporary world politicsl and the di versi ty of interests that emerge as societies develop. The controversy arises from different definitions of international pol i tics and foreign re1 ations and from contrasting perspectives on the nature of national independence. Through attempting to describe and explain such complexities and controversies, this chapter will examine Africa's place in world politics and in the global pol i ti cal economy. The complexity of Africa's participation in international affairs is twofold. Firstly, African states have to deal with a much longer agenda of issues and a wider set of actors than have existed before. Indeed, Africa and other Third World states have contributed to both of these phenomena: worl d pol i tics is now concerned with questions of development and inequal i ty as we1 1 as with war and peace; world politics now includes a vast range of actors--national and international, transnational and regional .2 These phenomena are, of course, interrelated: new states have drawn attention to their own problems and perspectives and have proceeded to create new insti- tutions and forum in which to present them. They have insisted that their dominant concerns are economic and political rather than strategic or ideo- logical ; for them, exchange rather than war is "high ~ol Africa con- sti tutes a majority of the new states and a third of the votes in the United Nations (UN) system; it has advanced demands from the poor for a new and more equitable world order. The international system, then, has become more diverse both in terms of actors and issues because of Africa's participation. The second aspect of the new complexity is internal, within African countries, and relates to the making of foreign policy. The response of African states to world politics involves a range of interests and insti- tutions, both national and continental. As Africa develops, so its social structure becomes more complex; the unity of the nationalist period is yielding to more specia7ized and stratified societies in which ethnici ty and race, region and religion, education and profession produce a variety of institutions and interests. The making of foreign policy is rarely open in any state, but despite its exclusiveness, it is usually subject to some pressures. In Africa, foreign policy is no longer the preserve of presidents; rather, a range of ministries, parastatal s and interest groups affect external relations. Outside pressures are a1 so ingredients in foreign pol icy-making; such external relations and demands are particularly salient for new, weak and poor countries .4 Foreign pol icy is a response to world pol i tics ; but no state can ex- cl ude external interests in its own deci sion-rnaki ng. Moreover, any expression of the "national " interest involves bargaining among several domestic actors. So both the internal and international aspects of contemporary world pol i tics are complex. However, the complexities should not divert attention from a few basic relationships, especial ly the balance between internal and external forces. The 1 i nkages between these are important in understanding Africa ' s international posi ti on. The analysis of independence, interdependence and dependence--of the proportion of domestic and foreign factors--rai ses questions of perceptions and controversy. These are unavoidable in any effort to explain behavior, particularly when issues of national security and development are involved. Nevertheless, in an attempt to go beyond description alone, we turn first to the nature of formal independence in Africa. This is a fundamental point in the analysis of African foreign policies; a degree of autonomy and power are essential in responding to international relations, especially if a state seeks to change its external environment. Pol i ti cal Economy of Independence Two very di f ferent perspecti ves have been i denti fi ed and used through which to examine and explain Africa's position in world politics: the dependency and the decoloni zation approaches. The latter view emphasizes change rather than conti nui ty, choices rather than constraints, symbol s instead of structures, and ideal s not economics; i t is based on the prerni se that formal independence leads to real power to act in the international system. By contrast, the more cri tical dependence approach suggests that pol i ti cal and legal independence does not by itself produce a new political economy; it indicates instead that internal underdevelopment and external dependence have been perpetuated despite any appearances to the contrary . The decoloni zation perspecti ve imp1 ies that the foreign policies of African states are true reflections of their new national interests and that they are sufficiently independent to make thei r own decisions. But the dependence approach suggests that gi ven Afri ca 's subordinate place in the international hierarchy, its forei gn pol i cies are largely determined by external forces and tend to advance such interests. Decolonization implies, then, an evolution towards a new pattern of relations between Afri ca and the powers ; dependency, however, suggests that gi ven established inequalities any reduction in inequality is unl ikely. These two distinct modes of analysis have profound implications for the way we see African foreign pol icy choices and for the assumptions with which African statesmen face the world. The contradictions suggested by these two approaches may be resol ved in part by making distinctions between pol icy and practice and by recognizing several different issue areas and levels of interaction. Firstly, Africa's ideologies of national ism and PanAfricanism, non-a1 i gnment and sel f-re1 iance are responses to its inheritance of dependence and underdevelopment. If we examine only rhetoric and declarations, then Africa would indeed seem to enjoy the fruits of independence. If, however, we also analyze its external economic and strategic relations, a rather different and much less autonomous image emerges. This relates to the second point, that of issue areas. African states display a1 1 the trappings of independence in the diplomatic issue area--they establ ish overseas missions, participate in the UN, and bring pressure to bear through the Third World coalition. Yet in the economic, strategic and social spheres they are dependent and even penetrated; they are characteristical ly vulnerable to external economic fluctuations, strategic demands and social changes. So Africa's apparent pol i ti cal decoloni zation may be contrasted with its dependence in other issue areas, particularly those that i nvol ve the great powers. African states interact at several levels--wi th their neighbors, in the continental system, and in the wider world system. Within Africa there appears to be a greater degree of equality and autonomy among actors than in the global sys tem. In the latter, inequal i ties and asymmetri es are substantial, with African states being concentrated at the lower end of the hierarchy. This i nterna ti onal dependence stands in contrast to continental interdependence. In addition to i ts es tab1 i shed geographic and raci a1 identity , Africa has its own regional organization and law, but it continues to be dependent on economic and military exchange with the world pol i tical economy. So al- though Africa has recaptured its political independence, its autonomy is stil l 1 irni ted by continued dependence on extern31 trade and investment, ski 11 s and technology, arms and assistance. There is thus a basic discontinuity between con ti nen tal diploma ti c interdependence and global economi c dependence. As the 1 eading African student of continental affai rs has observed, African diplomatic thought distinguishes between two forms of supranationalism: firstly, continental supranational i ty in pol i tics and, secondly, global supranationality in economics.6 A1 though the primary actor in the African international system is still the state, the number of non-s tate actors has increased rapidly since independence These now cover a range of issues and functions and collectively create the potential for greater African autonomy, particularly if dupl icati ve extra- African 1 inks are reduced. The most infl uential African organizations are economic or political in function, one indication of the imperatives of development and control. They are concentrated at the continental level, but the mos t-devel oped organizations exist at the subcontinental , regional level. There are some thirty continental organi zations in the OAU/Economic Comrni ssion for Africa (ECA) system, i ncl udi ng the African Development Bank and Fund, the Association of African Central Banks, the Association of African Ai rways, and the Inter-African Coffee Organization, and another seventy concerned with social issues, such as the All-African Conference of Churches, the Supreme Council for Sport in Africa, the Association of African Universities, and the All-Africa Trade Union Federation. A complex set of relations exists among this range of actors: that is, between the UN, its specialized agencies, the OAU, regional organizations in Africa, and African States. They exchange support proposals and are attempting to define their respective roles in order to increase thei r mutual compati bi 1 i ty . In addi tion to interstate organi zations there are also important trans- national institutions on the continent. In pre-colonial Africa, traders, missionaries, and explorers affected international relations ; in colonial Africa, metropol i tan admini strations and companies were dominant; and in con- temporary Africa, a rich variety of transnational actors, from mu1 tinational corporations to professional associations , are acti ve in the continental system. So the mixed-actor system is not new to Africa; its diversity and complexity, however, have evolved over time.' Thus the structure of the African international system has developed from a 1 imi ted number of essential ly bilateral relations into a complex web of bilateral and multilateral ties. Relations between traditional African nations were direct, 1 imi ted, and bi lateral . In the interregnum of the colonial period they became more formal, extensive, and multilateral. In contemporary Africa they are frequent, extensive, in- formal, and mu1 tilateral, invol ving both state and other actors. The impact of the latter on African development is ambiguous; some advance and some erode African unity and autonomy. African norms have developed para1 1 el to these insti tutional changes. Traditional rulers were concerned with their sovereignty in the face of external threats. Colonial ism confronted African val ues and stimulated the development of nationalism and PanAfricanism. Independent Africa has created PanAfrican institutions and norms which combine traditional values with contemporary imperati ves. African regional 1 aw is especial ly concerned with the protection of national sovereignty, mediation of disputes, treatment of refugees, and liberation of the continenL8 The international personality of African states was tenuous unti 1 the achievement of independence, but nonetheless existed in precolonial times; it is now unquestioned in world politics, although in the future it may have an increasing number of faces. International relations in Africa have always been largely intergovern- mental ; they have invol vec national el i tes , 1 ocated in major urban areas. They cont.ivue to be mainly 'official ' and to involve few people other than political ard administrative cadres, although institutions such as the Black Cultural Festivals, All-Africa Games, and All-Africa Trade Fairs may widen the interaction of some individual Africans with each other. The cause of African unity is now being championed by a mu1 tiplici ty of regional and continental organizations. Their goals, however, are essentially conser- vative in that they serve to support, not erode, national sovereignty. For example, the OAU tends to advance the interests of regimes. It has recogni zed neither secessions nor changes in colonial borders; it regulates inter-state relations, but does not necessarily advance the interests of the African people. The OAU system does, however, express Africa's racial identity in world pol i tics and encourages the i ntra-African resol ution of di sputes. PanAfri cani srn is expressed in the notions of "we are all Africans" and "try Africa first/"' Africa is still ambivalent about the acceptability of global norms and insti- tutions; whilst it uses its voting strength at the United Nations to make demands on the international system, at the same time it has attempted to increase its continental juri sdi ction over African affairs. It seeks support and assistance from the United Nations system; but it also encourages the peaceful settlement of local disputes through continental institutions rather than in the Security Counci 1. The OAU has helped to normalize relations after border, internal, or ideological disputes, but has insufficient authority to remove the causes of tensions. Consensus is reflected in the encouragement of "good nei~j- borliness" among a variety of African states, but the OAU has been permis- sive about coups and domestic violence in Africa. 10 The in ormality of the African state system stands in contrast to both imperial relations and contemporary world politics. Diplomatic initiatives or disputes are often the responsibility of influential leaders in Africa; their pol icies or agreements are later recognized and legitimized by the OAU, which has only a small secretariat and budget. The OAU system can bring about rapprochement, but is incapable of mounting sustained peacekeeping operations. Its approach to consensus and conci 1 iation revi ves pre-colonial attitudes of compromi se and coexistence. To date, however, regional and continental initiatives for cooperation in the economic and strategic issue areas have been less successful than those concerning less sal ient diplomatic or cultural questions. The independence of African states has been, then, 1 imi ted by relationships of both dependence and i nterdependence. Despite the characteris tic adoption of pol icies of African social ism and self-reliance, these nations are still dependent on foreign trade and capital , external support and materiel . They are a1 so increasingly interdependent i n the African system, as reflected by participation in regional and continental organizations and, through col lecti ve diplomacy, in world politics. African states respond to these two types of constraint in distinctive ways ; economic dependence is generally resented as a form of neocol oni a1 i sm whereas diplomatic interdependence is encouraged as an expression of PanAfricanism. Most regimes accept interdependence but reject dependence, at least at the level of ideology. However, the continuation of the dependence of African states--i n practice and pol icy--affects progress towards interdependence on the conti nen t. Dependence has begun to be modi fied by some countries through di vers i fyi ng production and partners and by adopting the "parastatal strategy" of partial state ownership. 11 On a continental scale, African dependence on external trade and capital is being challenged by the development of intra-African exchange and by the collective bargaining strategies adopted by African states in mu1 ti lateral institutions such as the European Economic Communi ty (EEC) and the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) . The character- istic "verti cal" pattern of trade and communications between African states and Europe is being supplemented and modified by the development of a "horizontal" continental exchange and infrastructure. For example, the ECA, in association with regional organi zations, is advancing intra-African trade and communications through a variety of projects, such as the trans-Africa and trans-Sahara high- ways, the Tanzania-Zambi a rai lway , and the Pan-African Telecomnuni cations Network. The creation of a continental diplomatic and economic infrastructure is a prerequi site for greater African independence. However, the infrastructure is still incomplete; moreover, its potential has been grasped by only a few leaders. The continuation and modification of Africa's dependence is symbol i zed by the evolution from "indirect rule" to "informal penetration." Colonial admininistrators, traders and missionaries may have been concerned not to disrupt establ i shed pol i ties unduly. But external intrusion nonetheless changed the basis of the power of indigenous rulers. Similarly, Africa's continuing dependence on foreign exchange and capital perpetuates subordination and 1 imi ts choice. Foreign entrepreneurs, diplomats, and experts may attempt to limit their impact on "national" decision-making and planning but in fact they have a profound effect on African societies. The choice of collaboration or confrontation is a continuing one in Africa, with important results for the development of the continent. African regimes have always been astute i n adapti ng to external opposi ti on and opportuni ties . Indeed, contemporary African 1 eaders sometimes justify thei r strategies of confrontation and col- laboration by reference to pre-colonial behavior.12 They selectively adopt or discard myths to legitimize their pol icies and control. But myths of equal i ty both within and between states have been hard to sustain under the interrelated pressures of external dependence and i n ternal underdevel oprnen t . Internal and International Inequalities Ideals of sovereignty and unity in Africa are based on the assumption that its states are equal. Yet the resources and rates of growth among African countries continue to di verge. Moreover, formal independence tended to exacerbate 1 atent internal i nequal i ties as a few indigenous groups took control of the state apparatus. To date, Africa has been preoccupied by establishing national control and extending i ndependence throughout the continent. In the future, however, the ma1 distri bution of power and affl uence both between and within states is likely to become a dominant issue. This tendency will be reinforced by trends in the global political economy towards scarcities of, and high prices for, raw materials and towards a redistribution of wealth internationally.13 Indeed, Africa may be returning to relations of realpolitik remin-iscent of precolonial international politics. The bases of power continue to include qua1 ities of leadership and ideology as well as possession of mili tary and mineral resources. But in a world system characterized by shortages and in- flation only a few African states are likely to achieve significant economic growth. The bases of such growth are either control over strategic products or acting as the center of regional integration; or both, given the relation- ship between national power and regional hegemony. Personal political leader- ship such as Presidents Nkrumah and Nyerere or ex-Emperor Haile Selassie - achieved will continue to realize influence, but the impact of their states will tend to decline compared with the power of countries like ~i~eria,~~ Zaire, Algeria, Zambia and Angola. This group of states is likely to achieve continental dominance because each of them possesses both minerals and the potential to be a regional center. Other states, like Gabon, Niger, Guinea, Libya and Botswana may have significant mineral resources, but their potential as leaders of a region is minimal. States such as Kenya, Ivory Coast and Senegal have few minerals, but do possess sufficient administrative and in- dustrial potential to act as catalysts for regional cooperation. The other states of Africa are primarily producers of agricultural commodi ties, dependent on a few crops and a small number of markets. If the mineral exporters and regional leaders achieve continental superiority, then the majority of African states will be subordinate. Only South Africa (and to a lesser extent Zimbabwe [Rhodesia]) now possesses significant mineral , industrial and administrati ve capacities. So African states can be usefully distinguished along several criteria, other than whether they are one- or multi-party states, civilian or military regimes, Christian or Moslem, Arab or Black. Relevant categories would seem to be national attributes, external dependence and (as we suggest below) degree of internal stratification or underdevelopment. National attributes include size of territory, population, and mi 1 i tary, and whether they produce oi 1, minerals, or agricul tural products. In terms of external dependence, the states of Africa can be compared by their commodity and trading partner con- centrations; that is, according to how many primary products they export and to how many states. Such categorization would indicate that Africa includes states which are both middle or regional powers and which belong to either the Third or Fourth Worlds. Africa, the largest regional grouping in terms of size and numbers of members, also contains the most land-locked and least- develo~ed states. Further, these tend to be the most dependent on a few ex- ports to a few states and to be those most affected by the energy crisis; they will also be most vulnerable to drought and to the new politics of food. By contrast, Africa incl udes several exporters of oi 1 (Libya, A1 geria, Nigeria, Angola and Gabon) and of other "strategic" comnodities such as copper (Zambia and Zaire), uranium (Niger, Gabon and South Africa) and phosphates (Morocco and Tunisia). Over time, the development prospect and achievements of these different groupings have diverged, leading to new continental inequalities. The larger and more affluent states have been subject to most external diplomatic and corporate pressures to be "open" to investment and to a "sub- imperial" role. The paradox of this small group of emergent "middle" powers in Africa is that they themselves remain dependent on external markets or sup- port. A1 though the propensity of extra-continental powers for direct or overt intervention has decreased, structures of dependence continue. The col 1 ab- oration between major African states and the great powers is no longer a simple relationship of domi nation; the middle powers of Africa benefit from their local hegemonies along with the great powers. States like Zambia and Zaire, for instance, are now able to play influential roles in southern Africa. This is exemplified by the involvement of Zambia in nenotiations towards independence in Mozambique and Zimbabwe and the role of Zaire in events in Angola as we1 1 as vice versa.15 But the maintenance of these regional roles is dependent on relationships with the consumers of copper and with the cor~orations which invest in the mines, industries, and infra- structures of the ~tates question. Similarly, the capacity of Libya and Nigeria to extend aid to the Sahelian states is a function of the high price of oil and the ability of these two states to spend their new income on international assistance as we1 1 as on industrial projects. The regional powers of Africa not only possess important mineral or entrepreneurial resources, they have a1 so become diplomati c centers for both the African and the global systems; most headquarters or regional of- fices of African and global organizations are located in their capitals. Further, they tend to have larger domestic products, armies, and populations than most African states. They receive aid from a wide variety of sources, especially from the United States, and are host to the largest number of corporate subsidiaries. Conversely, their balance of trade is most dependent on regional exchange because they are the dominant economies in their regions. Thi s set of characteris tics reveals the i ntermedi ate position of dominant African states in the global hierarchy;16 but on the continent their influence is becoming pervasive. Their relative affluence and prospects stand in stark contrast to the poverty and depression of most of Africa. Africa has always been peripheral in the global economy,17 its propor- tion of world trade remaining stable at about 4 percent. Its exports have increased by about 10 percent in the fifteen years since independence, but their direction remains predominantly towards Europe. Half the continent's export earnings come from two commodities--oil and copper; these along with coffee, cotton and cocoa account for mre than 60 percent of Africa's income from exports. The ori gin of these two major exports is concentra ted--A1 aeria, Libya, Nigeria, Zaire and Zambia receive over half the continent's foreign earnings and are thus able also to be Africa's leading importers of foreign capital and consumer goods. Moreover, most African states produce only one or two comnodi ties for export (e.g., iron from Mauritania, sugar from Mauritius, oi 1 from Libya and copper from Zambia) so their balances of trade and payments are extremely vulnerable. l8 Africa's oil exporters participate in the cartel activities of OPEC and OAPEC, with Libya having started the trend to state control over, and high prices for, oi 1 products. However, Africa cannot by itself, even if it were more united, maintain a high price for most of its primary products; it contributes only small proportions to the world trade in major raw materials. In any case, the prospects for producer power in most primary comnodities are slight: only in tin and bauxite, manganese, phosphate and copper, tea, cocoa and coffee could effective "trade unions" of the Third World operate, and then political will is essential.19 Africa produces 1/5 of the world's copper and 1/4 of its coffee, so it would stand to gain from producer power in these commodi ties.20 However, its experience in absorbing the high price for oil, fertilizers and manufactures is sombre: whilst a few, a1 ready re- lati vely advantaged, African states would benefit from cartel operations in such commodities, most would stand to lose from world inflation, recession and res tructuri ng.21 Other important industrial raw material s over which Africa exerts some potential leverage include most of the globe's cobalt, diamonds and go1 d, 1/3 of the world's chromium and manganese ore, 1/5 of its phosphate and uranium and 1/10 of its iron ore. Its exports of primary pro- ducts for consumer goods are less potent: 1/2 the world's palm oil and sisal, 1/4 of its groundnuts, and just 1/10 of its sugar, tea, cotton and maize.22 Not only does Africa produce minimal proportions of many conodi ties, the production of most is concentrated in a few states. Moreover, many of the minerals are located in Southern Africa and are at present controlled by whi te regimes and/or mu1 ti national corporations . Natural resources as we1 1 as national attributes continue, then, to produce a continental hierarchy in Africa. Africa's international inequal i ty is unl i kely to change for two reasons. Firstly, in an era of shortages and depletion there are insufficient resources to enable all states and peoples to achieve affluence; the ecological imperative means that many African countries wi 11 never develop unless substantial uni- versal redistribution occurs : "within a capitalist worl d-economy, a1 1 states cannot 'develop' simultaneously by definition, since the system functions by vi rtue of having unequal core and peripheral regions. "23 And, secondly, interstate inequal i ties are perpetuated by 1 inkages among ruling classes which share common interests in maintaining their own power and affluence; the leaders of Africa 's "mi ddle powers" recei ve support from external associates who become more important to them than their own internal constituency. The increase in i nequal i ties within African states is related to their unequal status in the global hierarchy and to the collaborative role of their elites. Indeed, the dependence of states is perpetuated by the interdepen- dence of elites. The cooperative relationship between local elites and the mu1 ti nati onal corporati on has been characteri zed as a form of transnational politics in which conspicuous consumption and foreign management techniques are transferred to and adopted in the Third World. From this perspective, it appears that the common interests of the rich states and the rich in the poor states have produced a dominant transnational associati~n;~~ has conceived, implemented and control led the characteristic paras tatal strategy in Africa to advance both corporate and indi genous interests. This "radi ca1 " transnational approach focuses on the mutual gains of an empathetic and sym- biotic relationship between external and local interests in the periphery. States in Africa may be dependent, but given shared interests, foreign and domestic el i tes have entered into a relationship amongst themsel ves approach- ing that of interdependence. The "symbiosis" of the African state and mu1 tinationals leads to ~utual benefi ts--investments, patronage, corruption and sty1 e for the new el i tes and markets, security and influence for the multinationals. The latter are adaptable, but the future of such "neocolonialism" depends on the accepta- bi 1 i ty of the bargain arranged between domestic and foreign rul ing el i tes. Revolution is unlikely in the near future, either in African internal or i nternational pol i tics . However, new paras tatal agreements may modi fy the attractiveness of the arrangement for either partner. Over time the "balance of power" in the relationship may shift away from the colonial inheritance and towards a greater degree of African influence and direction, especially if national resources or markets are of especial value to any particular corporation. 25 The ability of national elites to extract more benefits from the trans- national relationship may be crucial for their ability to repress, divert or co-opt internal opposi tion. Competi tion between national and corporate decision-makers takes place in the context of political demands within African states: In peripheral areas of the world economy, however, the primary contradiction is not between two groups within a state each trying to gain control of that state struc- ture, or to bend it. The primary contradiction is be- tween the interests organized and located in the core countries and their local allies on the one hand, and the majori ty of the population on the other.26 It is the tension between classes and other social groups within African states that leads to unstable foreign pol icies ; transnational el i te 1 i nkages per- petuate African states ' ambi valence as revealed in the expression of thei r "national interests." Foreign Pol icy: National or Class Interests? The foreign and development pol icies of African states can be best ex- plained by examining the linkages between "internal" and "external" actor~;~' it is through relations at this interface that the foreign policy, inter- national status and political economy of each state are largely determined. Independence involved a change of the dramatis personae of each country; it did not of itself lead to the re-establishment of national control over the economy. However, by ves ti ng formal responsi bi 1 i ty for foreign pol i cy in indigenous hands independence did create the potential for a successful assertion of economic and cultural nationalism. But any attempt by a poor state to confront an unequal world system alone is largely doomed unless it possesses significant resources or strategic position. Col lecti vely, African and Third World demands for redistribution and greater economic in- dependence have greater potential ; yet the maintenance of such unity is pro- blematic as First World actions tend to magnify diversities and inequalities within such coalitions. Moreover, in the first decade of independence most new ruling classes, especially in the more dependent countries, were able to rule only through collaboration with external interests ; to disengage meant i sol ation, intimi dation and obscuri ty--a situation that most fi rst-genera- tion nationalist leaders sought to avoid. Foreign associations also offered the prospects-- i f not the real i ty--of aid and capital , techno1 ogy and ski 1 1s , markets and money. Uhuru meant new demands on leaders for visible growth and continual patronage; the external estate helped to satisfy these initial demands. The elusiveness of real economic and social independence has led to coup d'etats, mi 1 i tary regimes and one-party states, a1 l designed to maximize control over the state and to achieve pol i tical order. Increased coercion and control have become imperative because of the process of underdevelopment and the inabi 1 i ty of the new state in Africa to contain that process. To overcome the dilemmas of dependence, the new class could intensify its estab- 1 ished external relations or change both its development and foreign pol icies to transform its inherited pol i tical economy. But the incumbents in most African states have opted for collaboration; only the few have chosen to alter their external linkages. Indeed, in most states there has been a retreat from, rather than confrontation with, the problems of development. The primary reason for this is that the new class . . . is not a class which is development-oriented . . . It forms either an expensive facade for a nation remaining basically stagnant and deprived, or a de facto intermediary for, a1 ly of, and expense upon, continued foreign economic penetration and domi nation. These characteristics go a long way . . . towards explaining the fragility of African political systems . . . . An elite which preaches austerity, efficiency, and development, but which practices 1 uxury (for itself and i ts government) combined with inefficiency, and which produces very 1 imi ted soci a1 or economic advances for the vast ma jori ty of the population--is inherently unlikely to maintain broad domestic backing.28 Most "political change" in Africa to date has been within the rul i ~g elite and has not often led to a significant redefinition of the state's role in the global pol i ti cal economy. In order to understand this phenomenon, it is necessary to go beyond the orthodox distinctions--such as those made between ci vi 1 i an and mi 1 i tary regimes, one- and mu1 ti-party states--and exam- ine the nature of a state's external and internal 1 inkages. This dependency approach assumes that the relationship between the ruling elite, the labor aristocracy and the peasantry is conditioned by the former's place in world politics; or, in other words, the extent to which the new class is a "com- prador bourgeoisie" is of great significance for the character of the "internal" pol i tical economy. As Leys asserts, "in post-colonial societies in Africa there can be little doubt that the dominant class is still the foreign bourgeoisie. "29 It is important, then, to investigate the salience of relations between external actors and the new class and the importance of an external "consti tuenzy" for the domestic pol i tical economy. Hence the central i1:y of international relations in the study of Africa. A crucial distinguishing motif for the two dominitnt types of political economy today on the continent would seem to be whether they are "state cap- italist" or "state socialist" regimes. Both types reflect the trend towards a concentration of power and affluence around state structures. However, there is clearly a difference between those states that presently encourage private capital (e. g., Egypt, Ivory Coast, Kenya, Nigeria, Senegal ) and those that now insist on community ownership (e.g., Angola, Algeria, Libya, Mozambique, Somalia, Tanzania). In both sets of cases the state exerts an increasing monopoly over decision-making, but in the former control, income and status are redistributed to individuals whilst in the latter they flow to new insti- tutions established by the state. This distinction between state capitalist and state social ist governments tends to reinforce the distinction between middle and other powers in Africa. For Africa's "great" powers are largely those that are mos t permissive towards western external actors. Indeed, there tends to be a high coincidence of interest between state capital ist governments and external states , entrepreneurs and corporations. 30 A1 though independence has had a minimal and delayed impact on the pol i- tical economy of African states, it has made the "national interest," as de- fined by the ruling class, a legitimate concern in the bargaining process between regimes and foreign actors. In general, it is true that "the inde- pendent governments of Africa are far more efficacious 'indirect rulers' than the obas and mwami s of the colonial era,"31 but a few states have begun to change both thei r external associations and thei r internal structures. There are, however, important obstacles to such efforts, which help to ex- plain the primacy of state capitalist rather than state socialist regimes. As dos San tos notes : . . . . if dependence defines the internal situation and is structur- ally linked to it, a country cannot break out of it simply by isolat- ing herself from external influences . . . The only solution therefore would be to change its internal structure -- a course which neces arily 1 eads to confrontation with the existing international structure. 82 Some African states have attempted this transformation of establ ished external ties and internal structures, often with a lack of success (e.g., Egypt, Ghana, Ma1 i and Sudan under di fferent governments). Only a few regimes have had sufficient longevity, innovati veness and support to undertake a sustained, longer-term reassessment of their inherited dependence and underdevelopment; but these experiments have produced various contradictions inherent in state socialism rather than any progress beyond in the direction of a more demo- cratic, decentral ized, "African" social ism (e.g., Algeria, Congo(B), Guinea, Somalia, Tanzania and now Guinea-Bissau, Mozambique and possibly Angola and Ethiopia). 'Progress beyond state capital ism and social ism is, of course, problernati c because the redistribution of benefi ts and opportuni ties threatens establ ished interests and institutions. 33 In imperial systems, colonies and their administrators were clearly subordinate to the metropole. In "neocolonial" Africa, new states and leaders have limited choice and autonomy, and yet "we have no fully adequate theory of the 'neocolonial state, ' its relation to international capital ism and domestic classes and its consequent role in the production process. "34 If we are to begin to explain the underdevelopment of Africa, its characteristic state capitalist systems, and its continued re1 iance on foreign aid, capital tech- nology and markets, then we clearly need to develop a comprehensive theory of the state in Africa. Essential to any such definition is an understanding of the nature of parastatal structures and the activities of multinational corporations. The political economy of parastatals and mu1 tinational corpora- tions is central because in most African countries these are the institutions through which the state and external interests come to terms. 35 The mu1 ti national corporation is a remarkably flexible insti tutiot and in the Third World it has secured access, profit and cooperation by permit- ting, even encouraging, national participation and 1 imi ted regional inte- gration. 36 The corporation has maintained the flow of raw materials, per- petuated its monopol ist position, and secured 1 ocal advocates by entering into cooperative branch-plant arrangements with national regimes or share- holder~;~~ incorporation and direction has enabled it to maintain its "global reach. " However, parastatal s, as local embodiments of mu1 tinational corporations, differ greatly in their nature and importance. In particular, some parastatals constitute an indirect way to develop state capital i sm through individual share-hol ding, whereas in state social ist regimes the government usually holds the local shares on behalf of the people. There is a major distinction between the impact and potential of parastatals in Nigeria and Kenya, for instance, compared with those in Zambia and Zaire and those in Tanzania and Somalia. But in both types, independence creates the possi- bili ty of a more intransigent foreign policy, or at least for some disrup- tion of stability. State control itself may at times be haphazard and un- predictable--both internal and international instabi 1 i ty may upset the logic of dependence. As Cohen has argued, ". . . the imperial 1 inkage is not so neatly facilitated nor so smoothly functioning as is sometimes assumed. There are real difficulties in guaranteeing the stabi 1 i ty of the peripheral capitalist system . . . "38 At times, then, African foreign policies can disrupt established transnational class relations and more truly express a "national " interest. The characteristic "parastatal strategy" of Africa may be an expression of national ism (as in state-capi tal ist systems) or a step towards national i- zation (as in state-social ist systems)--the "local i zation of capital ism" or a "social ist approach. "39 The former strategy of state capital ism does not constitute a fundamental challenge to the inheritance of integration into the world economy, especial ly into corporate structures and unequal exchange wi th advanced capital i st economies. Partial national i zation through state social i sm, on the other hand, does create the possibility of greater self-reliance and the potential for further moves towards a non-capi tal ist political economy, even if the transition to socialism itself is problematic. In the former, partner- ship with the multinational corporation is seen as the final stage of economic change--" the commanding hei ghts" having been conquered; i n the 1 atter, the parastatal strategy is conceived as just one step towards other socialist measures such as more direct political or worker control, different operating criteria, and eventual full national ownership in some form of cooperative structure .40 Moves towards and beyond state social ism in Africa are unl i kely because the interests of the new class are more vulnerable in a state socialist than in a state capitalist society. Further, given the pervasiveness of depen- dence and export-oriented economies, progress towards social i sm necessi tates more than confronting the mu1 tinational corporation. A foreign policy of both national i sm and social i srn requires a simul taneous attack on several forms of dependence. It is inseparable from effective national planning and a strategy which does more than reinforce elite privilege: "Establishing a system of state ownership within a capitalist world economy does not mean establishing a soci a1 i st economy. "41 Indeed, most moves toward national economi c control in Africa are motivated more by internal demands--el i te affl uence and control over the process of class formation--than by a desire to upset external link- ages. However, domes tic opposi ti on to the incumbent el i te may incorporate cri ticism of its foreign relations as well as of its mismanagement and indul- gence. The interaction of global and internal constraints and opportunities has led to increased inequalities within Africa, amongst classes as well as between states . Pol i ti cal independence has tended to increase economi c depen- dence because the new ruling elite has needed control over patronage and sym- bols. The new el i te has adopted foreign incomes and tastes42 whi le most of the population has been 1 argely forgotten and impoverished. The paras tatal strategy has, thus far, tended not only to reinforce the state-corporate relationship, but also to undermine any prospect of an indigenous entrepre- neurial class developing in Africa. In most states, indigenous capitalism cannot compete wi th the es tab1 i shed 1 inkages of dependence, the "monopoly in international commodi ty markets and monopoly in industri a1 technology. 1143 Local services develop largely in response to corporate penetration, not as an alternative to dependent industrialization. The elimination of a national middle class serves the interest of both partners in the parastatal system. Internal "class" interests may explain much external behavior of African states .44 Dependence reduces the foreign pol i cy "choi ces" of most Af ri can states . The pol i tical economy of parastatal structures reveals a continued impact of multinational corporations on the content and direction of national develop- ment. These structures give foreign companies the opportunity to captvce a market or source of supply, to export machinery or provide management and consul tancy services .45 The "partnership" forged during the coloni a1 period has been modified but not changed in its fundamentals: "The elites do not grow into an independent bourgeoisie because they cannot do so. They remain the junior partners of an external system upon which, at a1 1 decisive points, they must continue to depend. "47 In both colonial and post-colonial times, el i tes which col laborated with external interests became "parasitic" ; "indi- rect rule" led to reliance not on traditional ties or on an indigenous con- sti tuency, but rather on external associations. As President Nyerere insists, there is only one rational choice for Af ri ca--soci a1 ism: "Thi rd Worl d capital ism would have no choice except to cooperate wi th external capital ism, as a very junior partner. "48 However, for some states being a junior partner in the global capitalist economy holds attractions. As several critiques of the development of the Ivory Coast and Ghana show,49 a semi-capital ist strategy can be highly profitable in certain circumstances, both for the state and for groups within the state. Nevertheless, the cost of class-formation is high over time, heightened dependence increases vulnerability, and for Africa as a whole only a few successful capitalist rt imes are possi ble--some state participation or control is inevitable. The other, controversial class which affects both the calculation of the benefits and costs of collaboration and the orientation of a state's foreign pol icy is the "labor aristocracy. "50 The emergence of a workers' elite in state, parastatal and private organizations has served to widen the distribution of gains from independence and state capitalism and to co-opt a further social group, thus reducing the immediate prospects for change in internal politics or external relations. Despite some recent skepticism about the usefulness of the concept,51 the approach is helpful in explaining the lack of militant worker activity in Africa. Indeed, the coexistence be- tween the rul ing class and the labor aristocracy helps to explain why the former's definition of the national interest has rarely been chal lenged. The ruling class practices co-optation internally while it performs col lab- oration external ly. Together then, the transnational i zation and 1 abor aristocracy theses go some way to explain the absence both of revolution in Africa and of inter- national violence between Africa and the rich countries despite intensified inequal i ties and the paradoxes of state capital ism. Interstate dependence has benefitted a few in Africa; and together these few control the state machinery. Unti 1 other social forces demand participation in power and privilege, the external relations of the incumbent elites can be perpetuated. Even Leys admits that, despite the trend to monopoly and conflict in the political economy of capitalist African states such as Kenya, ". . . it would be dogmatic and mechanical to assert that neocolonial ism and underdevelopment must inevitably lead to revolutionary change in Kenya as a result of inevitable social and economic crisis. "52 Nevertheless, African leaders are concerned to increase their control and embourgeoisment. They have begun to redefine thei r collective ideology of nonal ignment away from pol i tical non-partisanship and towards economic confrontation. As the international system has moved / from bipolarity to multipolarity, from Cold War to detente, so Africa in its second decade of independence has trans formed nonal i gnment away from a concern with pol itico-securi ty matters and into a highly partisan demand for economic redistribution. Nonal i qnment and Dependence Africa constitutes the majori ty of new states in the nonal ignment move- ment, and has played a major part in the activities of the movement. As bipolarity gave way to detente and development to underdevelopment, so the Thi rd Worl d demanded economi c change rather than pol i ti cal vi s i bi 1 i ty. The new definition of nonalignment--which emphasizes economic opportunity rather than pol i ti co-strategic impartial i ty--and the new mood of confrontation were responses to the continuation of dependence. The novel ideology of "col lecti ve self-reliance" incorporates the national interests of a diverse range of states; it is both compatible with and supportive of the idea of nonalignment. However, each state's different positions and prospects make Third World unity problematic. As some countries benefit from close ties with major actors, different forms of dependence threaten the solidarity of the Third World, the very sol idari ty that is essential to escape from dependence. Africa has tried to relieve its inheritance of dependence by the a lop- tion of several international strategies: i ) national non-a1 ignment; ii ) regional integration ; i i i ) continental diplomatic interdependence; and i v) col lecti ve advocacy in international organi zations and global conferences. The first and the last are usually compatible and constitute a significant and potent combination in an era of resource scarcities and high prices. Yet, the incidence of dependence and the prospects to reduce it are both uneven. In this section we first examine some more of the characteristics of dependence and then look at Africa's relations with the great powers. These are both the major sources of dependence and the primary concern of nonal i gnment, whether this strategy is defined in pol i tico-strategic and/or economi c terms. African states are confronted with multifaceted and interrelated problems of dependence and ~nderdevelo~ment5~ are intensified for many countries by their small size and land-locked status. Dependence can occur in different domains54 and so pose a variety of political and admini- strati ve di lemmas. Wi 11 i am Demas has suggested that economic dependence is manifested in five ways in the Third World: a) dependence through foreign ownership and control of key sectors of the economy, b) dependence through forei gn aid, c) dependence through trade, d) dependence through re1 iance on foreign human resources and forei gn technical expertise, and e) dependence through imported consumption and production patterns. 55 To these we might add monetary pol icies, the mu1 tiple infl uences of the ubiquitous mu1 tinational corporation, and the phenomenon of transnational el i te 1 inkages. Outside the economic sphere, other forms of pol i tical , military, social and cultural dependence can be cited. Clearly these may be ranked in a different order for each state. But the importance of each form lies not so much in tangible results (over which there is some dispute),56 but rather in their implications for foreign and development policy and planning. The empirical impact of various types of dependence may be less salient than perceptions of their strength: de- cision-makers may believe dependence to be inevitable even if there are some strategies and choices which they could adopt to reduce it. Such psycho- logical dependence results from being affected by foreign values, education and tastes which cannot be realized in small, dependent political economies. Fatal ism, insecurity and instability mean that longer-term options are neither recognized nor considered; inertia and poor information further reduce the prospects for the innovation and intransigence which would be needed for a successful escape from, or redefinition of, dependence: "there is a need for a basic minimum of national feeling and self-confidence before room for manoeuvre can be studied and exploited. "57 The great powers, mu1 ti national corporations and international organizations have been able to penetrate African states through such elites. The major source of dependence in Africa is still Europe. Unl i ke Asia and Latin America, Africa has been of relative political insignificance to the super- powers and China. Its peripheral status in the triangular Sino-Soviet-American rivalries stands in contrast to its importance for Europe, both for the ex-colonial powers as states and now for the European Economic Community (EEC) as a collectivity. Whilst African transactions with the socialist states and Japan have grown at a faster rate than those with Europe, they remain minute for most states compared with substantial exchanges with the EEC, which now includes all the ex-colonial powers whose admi ni strati ve, educational and economic systems Africa inherited. Despite significant changes in some African states, many remain dependent on the values and structure; which they assumed at independence. These bilateral links have now been strengthened by mu1 ti 1 ateral associations wi th other EEC members, i ncl uding the economic center, West Germany. This crucial , compl ex and evol ving relationship has / recently been forrnal+ed in the Lome Convention between the EEC and the asso- ciate states of Afri: . the Caribbean and the Pacific (ACP).~~ Despite modi fications and reservations, the EurAfrican re1 ationship remains the most sal ient single factor in explaining the foreign pol icy orientations and development strategies of African states. Linkages between Europe and Africa are continual and pervasive, through the EEC as well as through the Comnonweal th and Francophonie, and through bilateral, biconti- nental and bi 1 ingual insti tutions. A1 though the concept of reciprocity has been abandoned and free-entry has been assured for most African products, Africa remains dependent on Europe. This is reflected in receipts from STABEX and EEC aid, in the fact that most foreign investment still comes from Britain and France, and that most of Africa's trade and technologi(:al exchange is with Europe. Moreover, Europe has its own favorites in Africa. In particular it has maintained close links whenever possible with those territories which in colonial times it had identified as administrative centers: "The four ACP countries with the largest and fastest-growing trade with the EEC are Nigeria, Zaire, Ivory Coast and ~en~a. This group of states has also been courted by other external interests; a few African countries may be able to play off the competition but most are condemned to relative in- significance. Given the gross disparities between the EEC and Africa, the impact of the former on the latter is often uneven and unconscious. Further, the replacement of a set of bilateral links by mu1 tilateral ones does not by itself constrain Europe's dominance. Thus it is hard to accept William Zart- man's optimistic conclusion that / From an evolutionary point of view . . . the Lome Convention is a we1 come development. Neither a neo-col onial consol i dation nor an institutionalization of dependency, it is a natural step in the process of decolonization, that at the same time strengthens the capsbi 1 i ties of developing African economies and pol i ties while di 1 uting thei r bi lateral ties wi th the metropole. 8 The provision for advantages to African states in the Lome Agreement does not remove inequalities between the signatories but it helps reduce disparities among them.6O The other major western actor in Africa is the United States, although Japan, ~anada,~' and Norway have growing economic 1 inks with some states. The role of the United States in Africa has been minor compared to its activities in other parts of the Third World, particularly those in Latin America, South East Asia and the Middle East. Moreover, its indirect and passive role until the 1960s, along with a marginal but fairly mutual economic exchange with a few states, means that Africa became an overt Cold War target late. Except for historical military or economic interests in states such as Morocco, Zaire, Ethiopia, Tunisia and Liberia. American concerns tended to be con- centrated in Egypt and in Southern Africa; elsewhere the U.S. worked through European colonial intermediaries.62 In Egypt and Southern Africa, strategic, economic and ideological interests led to American involvement in attempting to mediate complex regional disputes. The association between the U.S. and Israel and South Africa prejudiced its prospects in the rest of ~frica.63 Its actions in the Congo further reinforced images of it as a conservative, counter-rev01 uti onary actor. No American admini stration has yet escaped from this image, a1 though Henry Kissinger's shuttle diplomacy in Northern and Southern Africa and President Carter's 1 inks with America's black community and leadership may have moderated it somewhat. However, whi 1st the U.S. has belatedly recognized the inevitability of change in the Middle East and Southern Africa, its economic penetration has both increased and become more controversi a1 . In the relati vely optimistic first development decade, western, especially American, ideas of externally induced growth were widely accepted; but the failure of this initial develop- mental ideology has led to a more skeptical and pessimistic mood in the pre- sent second development decade.64 Given the demands for a New International Economic Order, American investment in Africa is now both more opposed and more vulnerable. So, at the very time that Africa's criticism of America's political and strategic policies on the continent has become somewhat muted, economic confl ict has prevented any general improvement in relations. Nevertheless, gi ven America's global dominance, several African states have been more permi ssi ve towards i ts economic, ideological and strategi c penetration, particularly those with a capital ist orientation. U.S.-Africa trade is concentrated in a few products and with a few partners: the U.S. buys oil, copper, coffee and tea--those comnodities identified above as most amenable to cartelization--from Nigeria, Libya, Ivory Coast, Zaire and Kenya. It a1 so concentrates its aid in these raw material -producing states rather than in the poorest, which export and import little. U.S. private investment has also been concentrated in this select group of states, in both oil and mineral production and in the manufacturing industry: The countries that receive the largest proportion of their imports from the United States are also the ones that receive the largest per capita amounts of grants, 1 oans, and private direct investment. These patterns are the context within which future e onomic rela- tions between the United States and Africa are set. 65 This concentration of U.S. interest and influence contributes to the growth of inequalities in Africa and, as we note in the next section, to the rise of sub-imperial ism. The ability of Europe and the United States to secure dependencies in Africa is increasingly matched by that of the Soviet Union. A1 though the U.S.S. R. lacks the wide range of instruments of statecraft--particularly its own transnational organi zati ons such as pri vate corporations, interest iroups and re1 i gious insti tutions--i t has establ ished common cause with several African countries, particularly with those a1 ienated by the west (e.g., Guinea, Libya, Uganda) and/or those seeking to establ ish social ist pol i tical economies (e.g., Algeria, Mozambique, Somalia), a question to which we return in the final section. The varieties of dependence relations between the great powers and Africa are wider than formal international 1 inks. Major intrusive actors have encouraged transnational as we1 1 intergovernmental relations. The west interacts with state managers and established interest groups; the socialist states have relations with parties, workers and 1 iberation movements. Whi le the capi tal i st countries develop transnational el i te ties, the Soviet bloc and China he1 p to support a transnational counter-el i te . Af ri can managers go to corporate meetings in Europe and North America; African pol i ticians attend meetings of the Soviet Communist Party and tri-continental institutions. But despite the range of possible 1 inkages, external influence in Africa tends to be unstable because of the characteristic instability of the continent's own pol i ti cal economies. The frequency of change and the difficulties of influence have led the Soviet Union to adopt a more pragmatic approach to Africa; it has abandoned its insistence on ties with national communist parties and on the adoption of "scientific" rather than "Afrfcan" social ism. The Soviet attitude to Africa has evolved, then, from an ideological and universalistic one to a more prag- matic and particularistic stance. Its policies and relations have become more calculating and self-interested. Its capabi 1 i ties are 1 irni ted so over- all its influence is weak. In particular its activities are challenged by diverse national and external interests, particularly the continuing western presence and the receptiveness to Chinese influence. As Africa is a more 4 complex and unequal region than it was before the era of detente, any attempt at exerting continent-wide influence by any external power is 1 ikely to be problematic. The rise and fall of Soviet-Egyptian relations is illustrative of the dilemmas facing any great power in Africa. Alvin Rubinstein concludes that Soviet infl uence over Egyptian foreign pol icy , even during the period of maximum Egyptian vul nerabi 1 i ty, was 1 imi ted . . . . Soviet pol icy seems to have made adjustments to Egyptian domestic pol i tics more often than Egyptian pol i cy-makers yielded to Soviet preferences . . . . The Soviet-Egyptian influence relationship is asymmetrical both as to its aims and accompl ishments . . . . The dependent member of a relationship has the ability to undertake independent initiatives, to the detriment of the donor's interests.66 But Russia would not let itself be influenced by Egypt to the extent that it would risk war with the United States; its reservations about extending a carte blanche to Egypt to fight a third war with Israel not only upset the regional strategic balance, but led to the demise of the Soviet presence and to President Sadat's courtship of the Americans; astute leaders can still play the 01 d pol i tics of nonal ignment'. Egypt resisted Russian infl uence wi th greater determination after the October 1973 war: "The USSR has invested billions of dollars in Egypt, but so far, it has been able to exert little if . any real influence over Sadat's foreign or domestic policies . . . . Soviet Egyptian relations have deteriorated sharply despite the massive Soviet aid during the war. "67 ?i ke other great powers, China has both widened its activities in Africa and concentrated them in particular states and parties, but its resources and interests are more limited and it is a late-comer to the race for influence. Following set-backs brought about by the Cul tural Revolution, China has establ i shed diplomatic relations with most African countries, thus excluding Taiwan and also creating the basis for influence both within the continent and against its own enemies. Like the Soviet Union, it has gradually shi fted its priorities away from support for 1 iberation movements and radical parties and towards regimes in power, especially when these are anti -Soviet. China has the advantage of being a non-whi te, non-European Third World nation, and tends to share more perceptions and policies with Africa than other intrusi ve actors. Through judicious, modest and generous economic and mi 1 i tary aid, through appropriate models and technology, and through an exchange of political support it has come to secure friends, markets and materials in Africa. China lacks the capabilities to act as a super-power in Africa so its goals in Africa are limited. Nevertheless, association with China can rein- force Africa's nonal i gnment, particularly its diversification of partners and disengagement from the world capital ist economy. African leaders are much less likely to fear Chinese hegemony than dominance from other sources, given its lack of resources and motivation; it is also part of the Third World itself. Moreover, it is no longer clear that China seeks continual rev01 ution and social change in Africa: "the short-term, pragmatic, evol utionary, and non-disruptive components of Chinese foreign pol icy have governed her African pol icy. "68 African leaders have ernphasi zed those several interests which are compatible with China's rather than alienate a leading member of the Third World coalition; they often share an identity of interest rather than being the objects of influence. It is indicative of China's modest ambitions and circumspect role in Africa that there is only one state with which it can be said to enjoy a "partial i nforrnal a1 1 ianceH--Tanzania. This particular relationship among "unequal equalsH69 may reflect a coincidence of world view and development goals rather than an expression of Chinese influence. To be sure, Tanzania sought support for its national development ar~d security and for the libera- tion struggle in southern Africa in exchange for improving China's respecta- bility and access in world politics. Its "rewards," especially aid for Tazara (a major rail road project) ,70 have been considerable, generous and timely; and yet there is little to suggest that China's "presence" in Tanzania is permanent or widespread. Its penetration of the Tanzanian society, polity and bureaucracy is minimal ; the relationship is exclusively official, bi lateral and intergovernmental. George Yu has suggested that the close association with China advances Tanzania's own policies and development, its nonalignment and nationalism, without leading to a new dependence. It is a reflection of comnon elite perceptions and shared goals within the grouping of non-a1 igned states ; Tanzania also maintains important links with a variety of African and Euro- pean nations, i ncl udi ng Zambia, Kenya, Bri tai n, West Germany, Japan, Sweden, etc. 72 Alan Hutchison also remarks of this important dyadic relationship that, "A position of privilege, even of prestige, should not therefore be confused with one of influence. "73 Moreover, a1 though China and Tanzania share many perceptions, their interests in China's major aid project--Tazara --are not completely similar: China emphasizes its contribution to regional integration and liberation as well as to its own status and economic possi- bili ties. Tanzania and Zambia attach more importance to the potential it creates for economic development, both agricul tural and industrial, a1 ong the new 1 ine-of-rai 1. 74 This asymmetry of power and interest generates mi sperceptions: "The misunderstanding about the friendship between Tanzania and China arises . . . because the benefits to China are intanqi ble whereas those to Tanzania are tangible.. . . I! 75 The one issue area in which the impact of great power rivalry is very clear is that of the mili tary. We turn to this question of strategic relations and the continental arms race before deal ing with the broader subject of sub-imperialism. Inequalities continue to grow between African military forces, with a few major strategiccenters emerging on the continent. The main sources of arms purchases, particularly in sub-Saharan Africa, remain France, Britain and the United States rather than the socialist states. Africa's mi 1 i tary might is concentrated in the north--particularly in Egypt, A1 geri a, Morocco and Li bya--and in a few black states--Ni aeria, Ethiooia, Zaire, Sudan, Somalia and uganda. 76 South Africa and Rhodesia maintain sig- nificant forces, of course, whilst those of Angola and Mozambique will have greater potential with their reorganization following their wars of 1 i beration. Over time, Africa's militaries have become more sophisticated, larger and better equipped, a1 though many continue to be diverted from an external role by internal security, political and economic activities. African states maintain a diverse range of military associations and agreements which in general reflect their overall foreign pol icy orienta- tion. The major links of the United States are with Morocco, Egypt, Ethiopia, Zaire and Liberia; the Soviet Union has training, supply and other understand- ings with A1 geria, Libya, Uganda, Mozambique, Angola and Guinea; France has a variety of military ties with the francophone states of West Africa, from Yorocco to Congo(B) whilst Britain has a few remaining links with Kenya, Ghana and Malawi. China has understandings with a select group of countries such as Cameroon, Equatorial Guinea and Tanzania, particularly with the latter; and Cuba has begun to supply training and support for Guinea and ~n~ola.~' SOW of those relations are long-standing (e.g., until 1976 u.S. military aid to Ethiopia, U.S.S.R. to Somali, France to Ivory Coast, Britain to Kenya and China to Tanzania) but many are more recent, modest and unpredictable; most African states continue to emphasize non-a1 i anment in the strategic issue area and are cautious about dependence on military ties with just one ?reat power. Several have preferred security relations with a group of foreign "middle powers" such as Italy, Yugoslavia and Canada. The next section is concerned wi th the rise of Africa' s own middle powers and wi th thei r ability to dominate regions on the continent. Reaional i sm and Sub- Im~eri i sm The present era of mu1 tipolari ty, detente and resource depletion enhances the prospects for a few states within the Third World to increase their own growth and influence. The small group of middle powers in Africa may be able to seize these favorable ci rcumstances to advance thei r international status and achieve dominance at the regional level. For the global hierarchy is not static; a1 though inequalities are likely to persist, movement up and down the ladder is possible. The upward movement of a few African states has siqni- ficance for other countries which are relatively subordinate and for the 1 inger- ing dreams of continental unity. Within the global system, a "sub-imperial" state is at the "center" of the peri~hery";78 it is a "client" which is able to exert dominance in one region. A sub-imperial state in Africa exerts a reqional hegemony within the continent akin to the global dominance of an imperial power; it plays an important i ntermediate role in a sphere of infl uence whi le remai ni ng subor- di nate i tsel f to major external actors .79 Sub-imperi a1 or "go-between"80 states no longer have simple cooperative relations with metropol i tan centers : 01 d dependence ties are evolving into new and more complex forms of a~~rnrnetr~.8~ I Nevertheless, it is clear that a group of leading African states have achieved both economic growth and military prowess because of their association with I major world powers and interests. The leading states of Africa are largely those most permissive towards international capital ism; they are characterized by a significant amount of external investment, col laborati ve parastatal institutions, de~endence on I regional exchange, and a trend towards domestic inequal i ties. They receive support from foreign investment and assistance agencies and are encouraged to play an intermediary role between the center and the peri~hery.82 However, thei r semi-peripheral status leads to ambivalence and opposi tion, especially from states in their region who are dependent both on semi -peripheral as well as core states. Regional integration may be either a voluntary or a coercive process; cooperative arrangements in Africa to date have been largely based on consensus, but regional exchange is now becoming an imperative for the manufacturing centers of Africa such as Egypt, Kenya and the Ivory Coast. Increasingly, therefore, regional cooperation may come to reflect the interests of national and foreign elites in a few African states and capitals; it may perpetuate the uneven development of Africa rather than advance continental development. Regional integration in Africa was first practiced by colonial govern- ments to increase administrative efficiency and economic opportunities. In contemporary Africa it has been widely advocated as both a path to Deace and as a strategy for development. The continued incidence of regional conflict and the perpetuation of regional decay lead to skenticism, however, about its inevitable efficacy. Moreover, a1 though regional organizations in East, West and Southern Africa have adapted to the impact of decolonization they are now threatened by a revival of nationalism based on the uneven distribu- tion of gains from economic cooperation. The major beneficiaries from the East African Community, the Entente, and the Southern African Customs Union have been the 1 eadi ng manufacturing and service centers of the regions--Kenya, 1vo:y Coast and South Africa, respectively, or rather the industrial complexes of Nairobi, Abidjan and the Witwatersrand. The maldistribution of industrial plants, infrastructure and services characterizing most reqional orqani zations83 hel~s explain the fluidity of such organizations in Africa; African states attempt to establish new organizations to avoid dominance from within Africa as well as from the global system. Regional inteqration does not always provide an escape from Africa's inheritance of subordination. Instead, regional integration in its present forn may promote both the underdevelopment and disunity of the continent. For regional integration in Africa is unlikely to produce self-reliance or integrated economies when some of its major advocates are foreign actors or col laborationist el i tes. Rather than advzncing disengagement from the global economy, such regional integration tends to encourage the es tab1 ishment of regional spheres of influence serving the interests of a few African and external states and elites. The master-plan of the Economic Commission for Africa (ECA) to create five sub-regions on the continent may further legi- timize such sub-imperialism. It would seem that the "second scramble" for Africa is not amon9 colonial powers but among African states, each of which is significantly affected by external interests. Political independence in Africa has tended to increase, rather than limit, economic dependence; economic growth has also declined and become more uneven.84 Most African states have very open economies and have been rather uncritical in their acceptance of corporate plans and activities to date. One result of development plans based on the parastatal strategy and associa- tion with external interests has been the heightening of internal and inter- state inequalities in Africa: a few African states and elites can exploit the overall relationship of dependence to their own benefit. For example, the Economic Conunity of West African States (ECOWAS) is but the latest in a series of attempts to secure both integration and dominance, in this case by a triumvirate of Nigeria, Senegal and the Ivory Coast. The concept of sub-imperialism is not only relevant for the analysis of western powers in Africa; it may also be applied to the close relation- ships already developed with a few African regimes by the Soviet Union. It may, in time, be appropriate to examine the dependencies of China and Japan in this way as well, but their interests are not yet sufficiently developed. Whi 1st the former seeks international respectabi 1 i ty and acceptabi 1 i ty the 1 atter i s primari ly concerned wi th exchanging raw materi a1 s for manufactures ; neither have wide-ranging interests in Africa to date. But the caution and modesty of China's Africa policy may be transitory aiven the i ntensi ty of the Si no-Soviet spl i t; Soviet-Chinese competition may come to rep1 ace the Sovi et-Ameri can s truggl e in being the dominant contemporary external ~atal~st.85 its quest for "influence, "86 "the character of Soviet objectives is broader than that of the Chinese both in scope (Soviet objecti ves have traditional ly been more differentiated) and in domain (they have also been pursued among a more diverse set of states). "87 Neverthe- less until Angola and Ethiopia and the dramatic display of Soviet ability to intervene in a distant civil war, the western states remained dominant in Africa--"the Soviet and Chinese ability to influence Black African re- gimes has remai ned margi nal . "88 However, the Soviet Union and, to a lesser extent, China have identi- fied a few states or parties which appeared to offer improved prospects for influence or identity of views over a range of issues such as development strategies and great power politics .89 Because of the greater time since its revolution and its more advanced economy, Russia has had a significant lead over China in the development of its pol icy towards and penetration inside Africa; it has been able to build on an established Tsarist interest in northern Africa, whereas China's pre-colonial contacts with the East African coast occurred much earlier and were more fitful .go Russia has abandoned its dogmatic Stalinist insistence on Third World states follow- ing "scientific" socialism and the Soviet model. Under the impact of resis- tance and fai 1 ure in the imnediate independence period its pol icy became more pragmatic and realist, favoring non-a1 ignment and a non-capi tal ist path, especial- ly disengagement from the international capital i st economy.91 The Soviet Union is concerned, then, not only with Africa's external relations but also with its internal class structures and development strategies. This com- bination of interests serves to justify its "penetration," or its "trans- national " association with "progressive" forces. Having abandoned its earl ier insistence on the establishment of communist parties in every country, the Soviet Union has tried to identify and support "popular" or "radical" re- gimes, parties or factions. Having rejected the possibility of a "Third Way" in the Third World, it now supports "African" socialism when it is ad- vocated by a "national democratic" state. 92 Its belated recognition of the tenuousness and distinctiveness of class formation in Africa led the Soviet Union to encourage a variety of strategies aimed at national economic con- trol , one-party states, industrial ization and working-class power. Its 1 ist of "revolutionary" states in Africa has changed under the impact of coups, but has included Ben Bella's Algeria, Nkrumah's Ghana, Keita's Mali and Nasser's Egypt. At present, according to Soviet scholars and bureaucrats, the select group of African states embarked on a non-capitalist path consists of ~uinea, Soma1 ia, Congo (Brazzavil le), Mozambique and ~n~ol The Soviet Union exhi bi ts considerable ambivalence about Tanzania (in part because of that country's close association with China) and hesitation over A1 geria; it has also encouraged rather cynical ties with two African gadflies--Amin of Uganda and Gadafi of Libya. In general, the Soviet Union has supported moves towards domestic social i sm and external diversification, especially when these pol icies have been expressed in a "Marxist-Leninist" language. The Soviet Union's pragmatism and "national interest" are often mi xed with a concern for ideological affinity and compatibility. As a great power it has significant geo-pol i tical interests ; where these coincide with pol i ti- cal empathy--as in contemporary Angola, Mozambique and Guinea--i t tends to concentrate resources. To be sure, it remains flexible and proper in its dealings with "moderate" African regimes, providing aid and investment for a majority of countries; indeed, "seeing the search for allies as almost chimeri- cal in the rapidly changing African pol i tical arena, the Soviet Union became primarily concerned with pure strategic interest."94 It has also come to realize that as classes are as yet embryonic in Africa and are not always the dominant social force, so the advance of capital ism and inequal i ties may generate class conflict and more orthodox class struggles. Much of its strategic interest in Africa has been derivative, based--1 i ke Bri tain's in the nineteenth century--on the centrality of Egypt in its "imperial" ambi- tions. Further, it is also an expression of its superpower role and the continuation of cold war realpolitik. As the USSR's capacity to intervene grows, so African perceptions of it as another great power - perhaps even in coll usion with the other, American, colossus - increase, coinciding with Chi nese views of Soviet imperial i sm.95 The consensus among Africanists and Sovietologists for the decade 1965-1975 was that "the Soviets are keeping a low profile in Africa. "96 Similarly Hall and Peyman recently asserted "that by 1975 China was more influential in Africa than the United States or the Soviet Union, not to mention former col onial powers.. . 'l97 Clearly these eval uations must now be considerably revised in the 1 ight of Russia's potential for further inter- vention in southern Africa through sub-imperial states 1 i ke Cuba, Angola, Mozambique and Ethiopia. Sub-irnperi a1 states may not only create regional integration, dominance and order; they may also act "by proxy" in regional confl i cts. Just as a few African regimes come to play a go-between role on behalf of external economic i nterests in advancing regional i ntegra tion, so can they serve as intermediaries in regional wars and arms races. Political and military clients maintain their own interests as well as those of their protectors; there may be tensions and disagreements between them as we1 l as col laboration. Nevertheless, through mil i tary and pol i tical support a poor state can become dependent on its supplier of arms, personnel and advocacy, as suggested in the previous section. The different external strategic as- sociations of African states have intensified regional tensions and turned border conflicts and so-called "local" wars into targets of great power at- tention. Thus the disagreements between Morocco and Algeria, Ethiopia and Soma1 ia, Libya and Egypt, Tanzania and Uganda, for example, tend to escalate-- in terms of visibility, intensity, destruction and salience--because of the considerable stakes which both African and external states have in the out- comes. Some of the political and security aspects of dependence are i 11 us- trated by the continuing comolex confrontations in the Horn of Africa. Tensions in the Horn have included the attempts by Eri trea to gain independence from Ethiopia, demands for Somalia irredentism against Ethiopia and ~enya,98 civi 1 war in the Sudan (which involved neighboring black and Arab states as well as Israel), the struggle for independence from France in Djibouti, the tensions between the three partners in the East African Comnunity, and disagreements between Egypt, Sudan and Libya. This set of tradi tional , border, 1 i beration, racial and ideological confl icts has been exacerbated and i ntensi fied by partisan external support .99 The Americans have withdrawn their undenvri ting of Ethiopia and have establ ished new 1 inks with Kenya and Egypt; the Soviets have shifted their commitment from Somalia to Ethiopia and have increased support to Uganda under Amin and Libya under Gadafi, but have been rebuffed by Sadat's Egypt and by Sudan after an attempt- ed coup; the British continue to provide military assistance for Kenya and are again cooperating with the Sudan and Egypt; the Chinese have become the sole suppliers of materiel and training for Tanzania; and a complex set of Arab and external interests have supported the 1 iberation movements in Eritrea and the Affars and ~ssas.~~~ J. Farer concludes in his study of the strategic and political issues of this region: "The Horn is not an especially hospitable setting for human habitation. But as a venue for con- frontation by proxy, it now shows real promise".lO1 Al though regional integration does often invol ve cooperation and mutual benefit, when associated with regional imperial ism, it may also consti- tute a form of structural violence for peripheral African states. The weaker states of Africa may become reluctant to "try Africa first" if continental mediation means accepting solutions imposed by a small group of more power- ful African countries. They may either appeal for more disinterested dispute resolution from outside the continent or attempt to establish new coalitions wi th foreign powers to chal 1 enge the dominance of a few African nations in continental affairs. In other words, African unity and autonomy may now be vulnerable not so much because of direct international imperial isms but because of the impact of inequality on the continent. Moreover, any trend towards a new diversity of interests among the states of Africa may leid to a revival of ideological disputes and new varieties of foreign policies. Notions of African socialism and unity, self-reliance and non-a1 ignment may be threatened by disparate national interests in Africa. New coal i tions both within the OAU and the UN may come to reflect the growing diversity of interests among both African states and the wider non-a1 igned grouping. In the final section we turn to an evaluation of continuities and discontinuities on the continent, particularly to an analysis of the prospects for greater inter- dependence and coexistence both in Africa and between it and the world. The Pros~ects for Se1 f -Re1 i ance and I nterde~endence Given the limited prospects of development for many African countries in the present world order, a strategy of self-reliance might be an appropri- ate response. Such a strategy involves attempts to avoid the problems of both class formation and external dominance, to go beyond nonalignment and depen- dence on a great power or sub-imperial state, by trying to implement unilateral- ly some of the rhetoric of the New International Economic Order. The attrac- tions of sub-imperial ism cannot be realized by most African states. For them especially, self-rel iance may be the only a1 ternative to continued, even perpetual, dependence. Sel f-re1 iance consists of pol i cies and behaviors designed to maximize national autonomy and to avoid having external actors decide the development goals and strategies for Africa. There are a few examples on the continent of states which have oriented themselves towards such a strategy of self-reliance. These states have started to change both their development and foreign policies and to forge new linkage structures, to put national interests above external ly-determi ned goal s and rol es . They have declined to have the character of their political economies designed for them by external interests and they have largely rejected the legacy of "deformed devel opment. "102 Self-reliance is related to a foreign policy of confrontation which seeks to change both external conditions and internal inequality by dealing with the two sides of the linkage; as such, it constitutes a reaction to dependence and an attempt to escape from it. The strategies of state capital- ism and state social i sm examined above are evol utionary forms of decoloni za- tion; a more critical view of dependence leads to advocacy of disengacjement and i sol ation rather than diversification or sub-imperial ism. Soviet scholars and dip1 omats have encouraged this more comprehensive response of sel f-re1 iance and have advocated it as a non-capitalist path. Despite its attractions for Russian pol icy-makers, it does deserve serious consideration as a strategy which abandons orthodox prescriptions and puts national interests above international integration. The possi bi 1 i ties of non-capi tali st development are clearly aided by the propects of increased exchange wi th the more i ndus tri a1 i zed soci a1 is t states, but such interaction is not necessarily characterized by interdepen- dence just because it takes place between "similar" systems.103 To be sure, social ist economies make different demands on the global economy and do not create the same imperatives for foreign exchange as do capitalist states and corporations. Nevertheless, we remain cautious about equating integration into the emerging social ist "world system"lo4 with non-capi tal ist develo~rnent. Soviet scholars in particular claim that Russia's internationalist policies "afford the young states which have chosen socialism as their goal the op- portunity to develop in that directionH.105 Yet their definition of a social i st-orientation is wide and uncritical --foreign investment and aid are encouraged as is "modern" technology, whi le external exchange wi thin the world capital ist economy is considered to be inevi table.106 Africa needs to feel free to examine a1 ternative formulations of na- tional and col lective sel f-re1 iance. 1°7 Given the imperative of the environ- ment it might a1 so useful ly examine intermediate and appropriate technology 108 rather than the capi tal-intensive modes of production advocated both by the mu1 tinational corporation and by the Soviet Union. Africa itself has to begin to choose between state capital ism, state social ism and non-capi tal ist development whi 1st recognizing that the choices are neither clear nor readily attainable. The present ruling classes on the continent will likely resist any demands for a radical restructuring of Africa's political economies. The establ ished modes of cooperation between national and international el i tes are quite well entrenched, and this is likely to make any transition from dependence to interdependence both di ffi cul t and protracted. In the absence of significant international and internal redistribution increased conflict and coercion are likely in the mid- to long- ten future.lo9 Because the ruling class in Africa is essentially dependent, it tends to rely on external support rather than on its domestic constituency. Because it is often unresponsive to internal inequalities and demands, it comes to rely on coercion as well as patronage for control. Yet Africa's leaders still seek short- term gains through external association, despite the long history of di lemnas inherent in such collaboration. It is understandable that instant panaceas appear so attractive. But it is important to recognize the rami- fications of such an orientation. In the absence of national development strategies adapted to 1 ocal needs, i ntegration into the global economy tends to promote foreign policies of compromise and domestic regimes of repression. Africa (i ncl udi ng ~anzani 10) 1 os t i ts i nnocence in i ts f i rs t decade of recaptured independence. In its present second decade, with the failure of optimi stic sol utions and predi ctions , cri ti cal analyses and better-defi ned development strategies are beginning to produce more informed and appropriate proposals, such as self-rel iance. However, the new elites of Africa remain unprepared for any radical change that upsets their comfortable re1 ationshi p with the external estate. To be sure, they are concerned to maximize benefits for themsel ves from foreign associations but they are not yet willing to restructure both their pol i tical economies and external 1 inkages. Opposition to this new class has been limited or contained to date. In the future authori- tarianism and regime violence, rather than rev01 ution and social ism, are 1 i kely to characterize African pol i tics .l l1 Africa has experienced false starts and the absence of ei ther growth or redistribution. These conditions as we1 1 as the underdeveloped class structures of African states are encouraging a trend now toward "departici pation"l l or centralization along with coercion. Pro- spects for change, participation and redistribution to benefit the many seem increasingly slim. External actors are 1 ikely to supply the means for such control necessary. These trends throw doubt on the util i ty of concepts such as "modernization" or "de~elo~ment"~ which imply that change is ultimately good for the many as well as the few. In any case, the benefits to be gained from dependence vary between states . The advantages to be secured from participation in the transnational elite differ between Third and Fourth World regimes in Africa. The Third World by definition has some resources to offer in exchange for a continued collaborative relationship; the Fourth World has 1 i ttle or nothing to offer. The Third World can as a group insist on a new pattern of interdependence in which a1 1 partners gain and participate as near equals; the Fourth World can only appeal to ideals of humanity and equality in any demand it makes for the relief of dependence. The Third World has orchestrated, and can bene- fit from, claims for a New International Economic Order; the Fourth World can only participate as a poor partner in the Group of 77 recognizing that any new deal between First and Third Worlds is likely to be disadvantageous to it. Despite the rhetoric in international forums and organizations and among aid agencies about special attention for the problems of the poorest, least-developed states, in practice the middl ing-rich now receive more. Unless very generous and much increased aid and comodi ty agreements are implemented, the Fourth World will continue to be impoverished114 while re- sources are redistributed between First and Third Worl ds. Africa stands to benefit less than most regions of the Third World from any new world order.115 A few of its burgeoning middle powers wi 11 gain as their sub-imperial role is reinforced. The identity of this minor- ity of countries may change over time as their leadership changes or their fortunes are affected by relations with the world economy. But the future Pax Africana will consist of a new continental hierarchy of increasingly unequal actors rather than a mythical PanAfricanism of equal states. The continent is returning to a mu1 tipolar structure in which a few regional powers dominate, as in the pre-colonial system.116 The mu1 tipolar global system has ambivalent implications for Africa. On the one hand the mu1 tip1 ication of power centers has enhanced the prospects for diversifying external relaticns; but it has also made the original con- ception of nonalignment vestigial. On the other hand, mu1 ti polarity has increased the number of potential sources of external penetration; it has a! so tended to exacerbate international competition, particularly the cleavage between the two leading socialist states, the Soviet Union and China. The current world order, then, poses problems as well as opportunities for African decision-makers. With skill, they can turn the contemporary system, its norms and institutions, to good advantage; but a naive approach to external intentions and issues wi 11 serve to intensi fy both dependence and underdevelop- ment. A few African leaders and organizations have been able to enhance their visi bi 1 i ty, power and development by recognizing current threats and oppor- tuni ties; but the majority of actors and states have been unable to respond to the revival of real pol i ti k. The di vergent reactions of P,frican countries and institutions to contemporary world politics further en1 arges inequal i ties on the continent. Until Africa establ ishes a truly consensual foreign pol icy in response to its corrmon inheritance of dependence and underdeveloprner t it is unlikely to achieve either development or independence; even the benefits of decoloni zation and interdependence may be elusive .I17 Meanwhile, the tendency towards inequal i ties in Africa perpetuates compl exi ties and insures that African foreign policies remain controversial in both practice and analysis. 77 END NOTES 1 For a succinct introduction to these see Seyom Brown, New Forces in World Pol i tics (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1974). 2 On contemporary "Trends and Patterns in World Society" see Richard A. Falk, A Study of Future Worlds (New York: Free Press, 1975), pp. 56-141. 3 On the associated rise of economic issues and regional and transnational actors see David H. Blake and Robert S. Wal ters, The Politics of Global Economic Relations (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall , 1976); Richard W. Mansback, Yale H. Ferguson and Donald E. Lampert, The Web of World Poli- tics: Non-state Actors in the Global System (Englewood Cliffs: Pren- tice-Hall , 1976); and Joan E. S~ero. The Politics of International Economic - Relations (New ~ork: St. arti ins, 1977). 4 On new states in the international system see Marshal 1 R. Singer, Weak States in a World of Powers: The Dynamics of International Relationships (~ew Free Press, 1972), August Schou and Arne Olav Brundi tland, eds., Small States in International Relations (New York: Wiley, 1971, Nobel Symposium 17), Steven L. Spiegel, Dominance and Diversity: the Inter- national Hierarchy (Boston: Little Brown, 1972), and Ronald P. Barston, ed., The Other Powers: Studies in the Foreign Policies of Small States (London: George A1 len and Unwin, 1973). 5 See I. William Zartman, "Europe and Africa: Decolonization or Dependency?" Foreign Affairs 54 (January 1976) : 325-343 and Sami r Amin, "Underdevelop- ment and Dependence in Black Africa : Origins and Contemporary Forms," Journal of Modern African Studies 10 (December 1972) : 503-524. 6 See A1 i A. Mazrui, "African Diplomatic Thought and Supranationali ty" in Ali A. Mazrui and Hasu H. patel, eds., ~friia world Affairs: The Next Thirty Years (New York: Third Press, 1973), p. 121 ; see also his essay on "The political Economy of World Order: Modernization and Reform in Africa" in Jagdish N. Bhagwati, ed., Economics and World Order: From the 1970s to the 1990s (New York: Macmil lan, 1972) ,p. 287-319. 7 On the emergence of a mixed-actor system in Africa see Timothy M. Shaw, "Discontinuities and Inequal i ties in African International Pol i tics," International Journal 30 (Summer 1975): 369-390 and "The Actors in African International Pol i tics" in Timothy M. Shaw and Kenneth A Heard, eds. , Pol i tics of Africa: Development and Dependence (London : Longman, 1979). For a rather unsatisfact0r.y overview from a state-centric and great power perspective see W.A.E. ~kurGk, Sub-Saharan Africa: A Guide to infor- mation Sources, International Relations Information Guide Services, Vol . 3 (Detroit: Gale, 1977). 8 See T. 0. Elias, Africa and the Development of International Law (Leiden: Si jhoff, 1972) and Felix Chuks Odoye, International Law and the New African States (London: Sweet and Maxwell, 1972). 9 See Vincent Bakpetu Thompson, Africa and Unity: The Evolution of PanAfricanism (London: Longman, 1969), Adekunle Ajala, PanAfricanism: Evolution, Progress and Prospects (London: Deutsch, 19l3) and Berhanykun Anderni cael , The Organization of African Unity and the United Nations: Relations be- tween the OAU and the UN (New York: Africana, 1976). 10 On the Origins and practice of African international law concerned with violence and interstate dis~utes see Adda B. Bozeman, Conflict in Africa: Concepts and Real i ties (princeto the tenuousness of African Uni ty - African Unity and the OAU (Lon n: see don : Pri nc Zden Fri eton Uni ek Cerve edmann, vers nka, 1977 i ty press, 1976). For The Unfinished Quest '1 11 The "parastatal strategy" in Africa consists of a set of arrangements between the state and mu1 tinational corporations. It characteristically involves a 51% state shareholding combined with a 49% corporate stake, with the corporation largely determining management and production goals and controlling patents, distribution and external links. The mutual understanding based on partial national ization and foreign partici~3tion generates symbiotic re1 ations between host state and corporation in which security and access are exchanged for technology and capital. 12 For analyses of pre-colonial di plomacy and international relations see A. Adu Boahen, "Fanti Diplomacy in the Eighteenth Century" and K. Ingham, "Foreign Relations of the Kingdoms of Western Uganda" in K. Inqharn, ed., The ~oreign of ~frican (~ondon: Butterworth, 1974), pr,. 25-49 and 161-187; J. F. Ade Ajayi, "Recent Studies in West African Di- plomatic History,"Niqerian ~ournal of International Affairs I (July 1975) : 39-46, and R. Smith, "Peace and Palaver: International Relations in Pre- colonial West Africa," Journal of African History 14 (1 973) : 599-621 . On contemporary patterns of African diplomacy informed by this i nheri- tance see R. A. Akindele, "Reflections on the Preoccupation and Conduct of African Di plornacy," Journal of Modern African Studies 14 (December 1976) : 557-576. 13 On these contemporary concerns see Timothy M. Shaw, "The Third World and the New International Order: Imp1 ications for Theory and Policy," Inter- Uni versi ty Seminar on International Relations (Ottawa) December 1976. 14 On Nigeria's emergence as Africa's leading state see Jean Herskovits, "Nigeria: Africa's New Power," Foreign Affairs 53 (January 1975) : 314- 333; Ibrahirn Agboola Gambari, "Nigeria and the World: A Growing Internal stability, ~eaith External ~nfluence," Journal of International Affairs 29 (Fall 1975): 155-169: James Mayall, "Oil and Nigerian Foreign Policy," African Affairs 75 (July 1976) : 31 7-330; and Olajide A1 uko, "Nigeria's Role in Inter-African Relations with Special Reference to the OAU," African Affairs 72 (April 1973): 145-162. - 15 See Timothy M. Shaw, "The International Politics of Southern Africa: Change or Continuity?" Issue 7 (Spring 1977); with Agrippah T. Mugomba, "Zambia: Detente or Di sengagement?" in John Sei 1 er, ed. , Southern Africa Si nce the Portuguese Coup (forthcomi ng ) ; and "The Pol i tical Economy of Regional Detente: Zambia and Southern Africa," Journal of African Studies 4 (Winter 1977/8). On the analogies between the contemporary hierarchy of states and that of corporations as expressed by the "Law of Increasinq Firm Size" and charac- teri zed by the concentration of production and decisi on-rnaki ng in global and regional centers see Stephen Hymer, "The Multinational Corporation and the Law of Uneven Development," i n Bhagwati , ed., Economi cs and Yorl d Order, pp. 114-132: . . .A regime of North Atlantic Mu1 tinational Corporations would tend to produce a hierarchical division of labor between geogra- phical regions corresponding to the vertical division of labor within the firm. It would tend to centralize high-level deci- sion-making occupations in a few large cities in the advanced countries, surrounded by a number of regional sub-capi tal s, and confine the rest of the world to lower levels of activity and income, i .e., to the status of towns and villages in the new Im- perial system. (p. 114). On Africa ' s persistent economic probl ems see Dharam P. Ghai , "Perspecti ves on Future Economic Prospects and Problems in Africa" in Bhagwati , ed., Economics and World Order, p. 257-286. "Africa, the Third World and the Strateqy for International Develo~ment in Mazrui and Patel, eds., Africa in worib Affairs, pp. 235-256, and his -toll ection on ~conomic ~ndependence in Africa (Nairobi : East African Li terature Bureau, 1973). See Eleanora and Robert L. West, "Conflictinq Economic Interests of Africa and the United States" in Frederick S. ~rkhurst, ed., U.S. Policy toward Africa (New York: Praeger, 1975), pp. 158-165. See the stimulating but cautionary essay on "The Potential for Monopolistic Commodity Pricing by Developing Countries" by Marian Radetski in Gerald K. Helleiner, ed., A World Divided: The Less Developed Countries in the Inter- national Economy (Cambridge: university Press, 1976), pp. 53-76. But it produces only 6% of the bauxite. See the useful table on "Africa's Share of World Mineral Production" in Arkhurst, ed., U.S. Policy toward Africa, p. 249. See Regi nal d H. Green, "Petroleum Prices and African Development: Retrench- ment or Reassessment?" International Journal 30 (Summer 1975) : 391 -405; Ernest J. Wilson, 111, "The Energy Crisis and African Underdevelopment," and G. E. Emembelu and S. S. Pannu, "Africa: Oil and Development," Africa Today 22 (October-December 1975) : 11 -37 and 39-47. An invaluable source of such basic data is, "Primary Commodities of Africa," Africa South of the Sahara 1976-77 (London: Europa, 19761, pp. 1119-1135. Immanuel Wallerstein, "The Present State of the Debate on World Inequality," in his World Inequality: Origins and Perspectives on the World System (Mon- treal : Black Rose, 1975), p. 23. See Richard Sklar, "Post-Imperial ism: A Class Analysis of Mu1 tinational Corporate Expansion, " Comparati ve Pol i ti cs 9 (October 1976) : 75-92; 0s.- valdo Sunkel, "Transnational Capital ism axd National Disintegration in Latin Ameri ca," Social and Economic Studies 22 (March 1973) : 132-1 76; and Martin Godfrey and Steven Langdon, "Partners in Underdevelopment? The Transnational ization Thesis in a Kenyan Context," Journal of Cornonweal th Politics 14 (March 1976): 42-63. 25 In his essay on "Europe and Africa" Zartman argues that "the dependency approach at best describes a static moment, while the decolonization theory accounts for changing relations by showing the origins and ingred- ients of the present state of affairs" (p. 340). We would suggest that decol oni zation has brought few benefi ts because of continuing dependence; dependence is perpetuated because of common el i te interests expressed through the transnational association. On the limited pros~ects for manoeuvre and economic decoloni zation see Robert L. Curry, Jr. and Dona1 d Rbthchi ld, "On Economi c Bargaining between Afri can Governments and Mu1 ti -national Companies," Journal of Modern Afri can Studies 12 (June 1974) : 173-191. 26 Imnanuel Wal lerstein, "Class and Class Conflict in Contemporary Africa," Canadian Journal of African Studies 7 (1973): 380. 27 See Timothy M. Shaw, "The Political Economy of African International Relations," Issue 5 (Winter 1975) : 29-38 and "African States and Inter- national Stratification: The Adaptive Foreign Policy of Tanzania" in Ingham, ed., The Foreign Relations of African States, pp. 231-236. 28 Reginald H. Green, "Political Independence and the National Econorqy: An Essay on the Political Economy of Decolonization," in Christopher Allen and R. W. Johnston, eds., ~frican Papers in the History, Pol i tics and Economics of Africa Presented to Thomas Hodgkin (Cambridge: Uni versi ty Press, 1970), pp. 275-276. 29 Colin Levs, "The 'Over-developed' Post Colonial State: A Re-eval uation." Review o-f African Political cono om^ 5 (January-April 1976) : 44. For a- case study of the roles and relations of "external" actors in the making of development and foreign policy in one African state see Timothy M. - Shaw, "The Foreign Pol icy system of Zambia ," African Studies Review 19 (Apri 1 1976) : 31 -66. For further conceptualization and cases see Carl Widstrand, ed., Mu1 tina- tional Fi rms in Africa (Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1975) and Henry 1. Bretton, Direct Foreign Investment in Africa: Its Pol i tical Purpose and Function in Patron-Cl ient Relations (New York: General Learning Press, 1976). 31 Inanuel Wallerstein, "Africa in a Capitalist World," Issue 3 (Fall 1973): 9. 32 T. dos Santos, "The Crisis of Development Theory and the Problem of Depen- dence in Latin America," in Henry Berstein, ed., Underdevelopment and Devel opmen t : The Thi rd Worl d Today (Harrnondsworth : Pengui n, 1973), p. 79. 33 For critiques of socialist practice in Africa, especially Tanzania, from a radical 'perspecti ve which. advocates change beyond state social ism see inter alia. "S~ecial Issue on the Political Economv of Parastatals," Eastern ~frican Review 5 (1972) ; John Loxley &d John S. Saul, "Mul- ti national s , Workers and Paras tatal s i n Tanzania, " Review of Afri can Pol i tical Economy 2 (January-Apri 1 1975) : 54-88; Brian Van Arkadie, "Development of the State Sector and Economic Independence. " i n Ghai , ed., Economic Independence in Africa, pp. 33-122; ~ustinian et a1 . , - eds., Towards Social ist Planninq (Dar es Salaam: Tanzania Publ ishing House, 1972) ; I. G. Shi vji , "Capi tal ism Unl imi ted; Publ i c Corporations in Partner- ship with Mu1 tinational Corporations," Africa Review 3 (1973) : 359-382; and I. G. Shivji, Class Struggles in Tanzania (London: Heinernann, 1976). 34 John S. Saul, "The Political Aspects of Economic Independence," in Ghai, ed., Economic Independence in Africa, p. 135. But also see Sklar, "Post- Imperial i srn. " 35 On the case of Zambia see Timothy M. Shaw, Dependence and Underdevelop- ment: The Development and Foreign Policies of Zambia, Papers in Inter- national Studies, Africa Series, no. 28 (Athens : Ohio university, 1976) and "Zambia: Dependence and Underdevelopment," Canadian ~ournal- Afri- can Studies 10 (1976): 3-22; Richard 1. Sklar, Corporate Power in an African State: The Pol i tical Impact of Mu1 tinational Mining Companies in Zambia (Berkeley: University of Cal ifornia Press, 1975); and Anthony Martin, Minding their own Business : Zambia's Struqgl e against Western , Control (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1975). 36 See Norman Gi rvan, "Economic Nati onal i sts v. Mu1 ti national Corporations : Rev01 utionarj or Evol utionary Change" in Wi dstrand, ed. , Mu1 tinational Firms in Africa, pp. 25-56. For a rather uncritical review of African responses see Lesl ie L. Rood, " Forei qn Investment i n African Manufactur- ing," Journal of Modern African studies 13 (March 1975): 19-34 and "Na- tional ization and Indigenization in Africa," Journal of Modern African Studies 14 (September 1976): 427-447. For a critique of corporate advocacy of regionalism see B. W. T. Mutharika, "Multinational Corporations in Region- al Integration: The African Experience," African Review 5 (1975) : 365-390. 37 On the varieties of corporate-paras tatal arrangements see Ann Sei dman, "Multinational Corporations and Economic Independence in Africa," Afri- can Social Research 19 (June 1975): 739-750, "Old Motives, New Methods: Foreign Enterprise in Africa Today," in Allen and Johnson, eds., African Pers ecti ves, pp. 251-272 and Planning for Development in Sub-Saharan Africa New York: Praeger, 1974). Also see Widstrand, ed., Mu1 tinational -7- Firms in Africa. On the archtypical "African" corporation see S. Cronje, M. Ling and G. Cronje, LONRHO: Portrait of a Mu1 tinational (Harmondsworth: Pel i can, 1976). 38 Robin Cohen, "Editorial: The State in Africa," Review of African Politi- cal Economy 5 (January-April 1976): 2. 39 See Ghai, "Introduction" in the collection on Economic Independence in Africa: p. xiii. 40 See Clive Y. Thomas, "Industrialization and the Transformation of Africa: An A1 ternati ve to MNC Expansion," in Wi dstrand, ed., Mu1 tinational Firms in Africa, pp. 325-360. 41 Immanuel Wall erstei n, "Dependence in an Interdependent Nor1 d: The Limited Possibilities of Transformation within the Capitalist World Economy," African Studies Review 17 (April 1974): 22. 42 See Steven Langdon, "Multinational Corporations, Taste Transfer and Under- development: A Case Study from Kenya," Review of African Political Econo- 9 2 (January-April 1975): 12-35. 43 Col in Leys, Underdevelopment in Kenya: The Pol i ti cal Economy of Neocolon- ial ism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1974), p. 11. 44 See Timothy M. Shaw, "The Foreign Policy of Zambia: Ideology and Interests," Journal of Modern African Studies 14 (March 1976): 79-105 and "Zambia's Foreign Policy," in Olajide Aluko, ed., The Foreign Policies of African States (London : Hodder and Stoughton, 1977), pp. 220-234. 45 See Brian van Arkadie, "Development of the State Sector and Economic In- dependence," in Ghai, ed., Economic Independence in Africa, pp. 88-122. 46 For a comprehensi ve case study see Jus ti nian Rweyamamu, Underdevelcoment and Industrial ization in Tanzania (Nairobi : Oxford University Press, 1973). 47 Basi 1 Davi dson, Can Africa Survive? Arguments against Growth without Development (Boston: Little Brown, 1974),p. 85. On the possibilities of a more national and less comprador bourgeoisie see Paul Kennedy, "Afri- can Businessmen and Foreign Capi tal : Col laboration or Confl ict?" Afri- can Affairs 76 (April 1977), 177-194. 48 Julius K. Nyerere, "The Rational Choice: in his Freedom and Development: Uhuru Na Maendeleo (Dar es Salaam: Oxford University Press, 1973), p. 384. See Philip Foster and Aristide R. Zolberg, eds., Ghana and the Ivory Coast: Perspectives on Modernization (Chicago: University of Chica o Press, 1971) Jon Woronoff, West African Wager: Houphouet versus Nkrurnah 9 Metuchen: Sca crow, 1972) ; and Sami r Amin, Neocolonial ism in West Africa (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973). Giovannie Arrighi and John S. Saul, " International Corporations, Labor Aristocracies and Economic Development in Tropical Africa,'' in their Essays on the Political Economy of Africa (~ew Monthly Review, 1973), p. 141. See Richard Sandbrook and Robin Cohen, "Workers and Progressive Change in Underdeveloped Countries," in their, The Develo~ment of an African Working class :' Studies in Class orm mat ion and ~ction Univer- sity of Toronto Press, 1971) pp. 1-9 and Issa Shiv.ii, "Peasants and Class - .. A1 liances ," Review of African Pol i ti cal Economy 3 j~a~-october : 10-18. Leys, Underdevelopment in Kenya, p. 274. For useful introductions to dependence and underdevel opment from a vari- ety of perspectives consul t Henry Bernstein, ed., Underdevelopment and Development: The Third World Today (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973); re- James D. Cockcroft, Andre Gunder Frank and Dale L. Johnson, Dependence and Underdevelopment: Latin America's Pol i tical Economy (New York: Anchor, 1972) : Robert I. Rhodes, ed., Imperial ism and Underdevelopment: A Reader (New York: Monthly Review, 1970); and Charles K. Wilber, ed., The Pol i tical Economy of Development and Underdevelopment (New York: Random House, 1973). 54 On the pervasive economic dependence on external capital , trade and skills see Barbara Stallings, "Economic Dependency in Africa and Latin America," Sage Professional Papers in Comparative Politics 3 (1972). 55 William G. Demas, "Economic Independence: Conceptual and Policy Issues in the Commonwealth Caribbean," in Percy Selwyn, ed., Development Policy in Small Countries (London: Croom Helm for IDS, 1975), p. 194. 56 On the debate over indicators of dependence and possible empirical tests through which to eval uate its impact and interrelations see Patrick J. McGowan, "Economic Dependence and Economic Performance in Black Africa," Journal of Modern African Studies 14 (March 1976) : 25-40; P. J. ~c~owan Dale L. Smith, "Economic Dependency in Black Africa: A Causal Analysis of Competing Theories," paper presented at a meeting of the ~nternatiohal Studies Association, St. Louis, March 1977; Richard Vengroff, "Neo-colo- nial ism and Pol icy Outputs in Africa," Comparative pol itical Studies 8 (July 1975): 234-250; and R. Vengroff, "Dependency, Development and In- equality in Black Africa," paper presented at a meeting of the African Studies Association, Boston, November 1976. These essays reveal as much about the disparate sociology of knowledge as about the correlates of dependence. Most advocates of dependence woul d be skeptical about the utility or appropriateness of such empirical tests. See, for instance, the critique by Shei la M. Smith, "Economic Dependence and Economic Ernpi ricism in Black Africa," Journal of Modern African Studies 15 (March 1977): 116-118. 57 Percy Selwyn, "Introduction: Room for Manoeuvre?" in the collection on Development Policy in Small Countries, p. 18. / 58 On the Lome Convention see Nicholas Hutton, "Africa's Changing Relation- ship with the EEC," World Today 30 (October 1974) : pp. 426-435 and Isebill V. Gruhn, "The om: Convention : Inching towards Interdependence," Inter- national Organization 30 (Spring 1976) : 241-262. Cf. Johan 5al tun-he Lorn6 Convention and Neo-capi tal ism" and R. H. Green, "The Lome Convention ," African Review 6 (1976): 35-54 and B. Dolan, "The ~ome' Convention and Europe's Relationship with the Third \#lor1 A Critical Analysis ," paper presented at a meeting of the International Studies Association, St. Louis, March 1977. 59 Timothy Curtin, "Africa and the EEC: ,The ~ornl Convention," Africa South of the Sahara 1976-77, p. 52. On Lome and inequality in Africa see Esko Antola, "The European Communi ty and Africa: A Neo-Colonial Model of De- velopment, " Peace and Sciences (Vienna : International Insti tute for Peace, 1976) and Jyrki Kakonen, "Effects of the EEC Association on Foreign Trade and Diplomatic Relations of the African States," University of Turku Studies in Political Science 5 (1976). 60 Zartman, "Europe and Africa," pp. 342 and 343. On Canada's interests in Africa see Robert 0. Matthews, "Canada and Anqlo- phone Africa" and Louis Sabourin, "Canada and Francophone Africa," in Peyton V. Lyon and Tareq Y. Ismael, eds., Canada and' the Third World (To- ronto: Macmillan, 1976), pp. 60-161, and Timothy M. Shaw,"Zarnbia and Canada: Diplomacy in Southern Africa," in Denis Stairs and Don Munton, eds., Canada in Worl d Perspectives (forthcoming) . See the persuasive and critical essay by Imnanuel Wal lerstein, "Africa, the United States and the World Economy: The Historical Bases of American Policy," in Arkhurst, ed., U.S. Policy toward Africa, pp. 11-37. See Timothy M. Shaw, "Oil, Israel and the OAU: An Introduction to the Pol i tical Economy of Energy in Southern Africa," Africa Today 23 (Jan- uary-March 1976): 15-26, and Elliott P. Skinner, "African States and Israel : Uneasy Relations in a World of Crises," Journal of African Studies 21 (Spring 1975): 1-23. On the evol ution of this development ideology see Robert A. Packenhar'', Liberal America and the Third world: pol i tical Development Ideas in- Foreign Aid and Social Science (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1973). For a pessimistic analysis of the current prospects for both development and U.S. infl uence see Nelson Kasfir, "~nterde~endence American Commitment to Promote Development in the Third World: Africa - the Hardest Case," in David A. ~aldwin, ed., America in an Interdepen- dent World: Problems of United States Foreign Policy (Hanover, NH: Uni- versity Press of New England, 1976), pp. 223-243. West and West, "Conflicting Economic Interests of Africa and the United States," in Arkhurst, ed., U.S. Policy toward Africa, p. 179. This con- tribution and the collection's appendix contain useful data on economic exchange between Africa and the world economy. A1 vin Z. Rubinstein, "The Soviet-Egyptian Infl uence Relationship since the June 1967 War," in Michael MccGwire, Ken Booth, John McDonnell, eds., Soviet Naval Pol icy: Objectives and Constraints (New York: Praeger, 1975), pp. 175-177. Robert 0. Freedman, "The Soviet Union and Sadat's Egypt" in ibid., p. 230; see also his Soviet Policy toward the Middle East Since 1970 (New York: Praeger, 1975): "given the overall Soviet goal of expelling western in- fluence from the Middle East, the Soviet leadership seems willing to con- tinue to provide large amounts of mil i tary and economic aid as we1 1 as diplomatic support to Arab regimes that often oppose the USSR, in the hope of spurring anti -western trends in the region. . .the Soviet leaders seem will ing to pay the costs invol ved in pursuing such a pol icy because they have made the basic decision that the Middle East is a region of major importance to the Soviet Union." (p. 179) Bruce D. Larkin, China and Africa 1949-1970: The Foreign Policy of the People ' s Republ i c of China (Berkeley : Uni versi ty of Cal i forni a Press, 1971), p. 210. See also Alaba Ogunsanwo, China's Policy in Africa, 1958- 1971 (Cambridge: University Press, 1974) and Wolfgang Bartke, China's Econorni c Aid (New York: Holmes and Meier, 1975. ) George T. Yu, China's African Policy: A Study of Tanzania (New York: Praeger, 1975), pp. xv and 52. Ibid., pp. 73-85 and 125-148; see also Martin Bailey, Freedom Railway: China and the Tanzania-Zambia Link (London: Rex Coll ings, 1976) and Richard Hall and Hugh Peyrnan, The Great Uhuru Railway: China's Showpiece in Africa (London: Go1 lancz, 1976). Yu, China's African Policy, p. 86. Ibid, pp. 87-91. Alan Hutchison, China's African Revolution (London : Hutchinson, 1975), p. 272. These different emphases are reflected in Hugh and Peyrnan, The Great Uhuru Railway who place more importance on its strategic and political impact on African and international pol i tics and Bailey, Freedom Railway who stresses its economic and integrative potential. Hutchison, China's African Revolution, p. 278. See The Mil i tary Balance 1976-1977 (London: International Institute for Strategic Studies, 1976), pp. 31-48 and 94-95. See also SIPRI, Arms Trade wi th the Thi rd Worl d (Harmondsworth : Pel i can, 1975), pp. 200-258. The Mi 1 i tary Balance 1976-1 977, pp. 31 and 41 . See Arrighi and Saul, "National ism and Rev01 ution in Sub-Saharan Africa," in their Essays on the Pol i tical Economy of Africa, pp. 49 and 76. See Timothy M. Shaw, "Regional Cooperation and Conflict in Africa," Inter- national Journal 30 (Autumn 1975) : 671-688. See Johan Galtung, "A Structural Theory of Imperialism," Journal of Peace Research 2 (1971): 104-105; see also his "Conflict on a Global Scale: Social lmpe;ial ism and sub-imperial ism - Continuities in the Structural Theory of Imperial ism," World Development 4 (March 1976) : 153-165. See Timothy M. Shaw, "International Stratification in Africa: Sub-im- perial ism in Eastern and Southern Africa," Orbis 21 (Summer 1977). Cf. Zartman, "Europe and Africa," p. 341. See also his essay, "Africa," in James N. Rosenau, Kenneth W. Thompson, Gavin Boyd, eds., World Politics: An Introduction (New York: Free Press, 1976), pp. 569-594. See Lynn K. Mytelka, "The Distribution of Gains in Third World Integrative Systems," World Politics 25 (January 1973): 236-250 and "A Genealogy of Francophone West and Equatorial African Regional Organizations ," Journal of Modern African Studies 12 (July 1974): 297-320. Also see James H. Mi ttleman, "The Development of Post-colonial African Regional ism and the Formation of the OAU," Kroniek van Afrika 2 (1971): 83-105. See Ghai , "Perspectives on Future Economic Problems and Prospects in Africa" and "Africa, the Thi rd Worl d and the Strategy for International Development". On the impact and implications of this split in Southern Africa see Colin Legum, "The Soviet Union, China and the West in Southern Africa," Foreign Affairs 54 (July 1976): 745-762. For an attempt to employ this central but elusive concept see Alvin Z. Rubinstein, ed., Soviet and Chinese Influence in the Third World (New York: Praeger, 1975). See also Warren Weinstein, ed., Chinese and Soviet Aid to Africa (New York: Praeger, 1975). Robert Legvold, "Soviet and Chinese Influence in Black Africa" in Rubin- stein, ed., Soviet and Chinese Influence in the Third World, p. 159. Ibid., p. 167. See Helen Desfosses Cohn, Soviet Policy toward Black Africa: The Focus on National Integration (New York: Praeger, 1972). Cf. the more ortho- dox but less persuasive analysis of the superpowers as actors concerned primarily with inter-, rather than intra-, state relations in W.A.E. Skurni k, "Africa and the Superpowers ,'I Current Hi story 71 (November 1976) : 145-148. See Edward T. Wilson, Russia and Black Africa before World War I1 (New York: Holmes and ~eier, 1974) and Teobaldo Filesi, China and ~friia the Middle Ages (London: Cass, 1972). On the dilemmas which Africa poses in terms both of tactics and ideology, and on the trend towards pluralism, diversity and conservatism in the social ist world's relations with the continent see Zbigniew Brzezinski , ed., Africa and the Communist World (Stanford: Stanford University Press for Hoover Institution, 1963). The Soviet Union distinguishes countries in the Third World along three basic indicators:"l) the class or classes that are in power; 2) the type of foreign pol icy that is pursued; and 3) the nature of the domestic po- licies that are implemented." Roger E. Kanet, "Soviet Attitudes toward - Developing Nations since Stalin," in his collection on The Soviet Union and the Developing Nations (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins, 1974), p. 44. On socialism in Libya, Algeria, Mali, Ghana and Tanzania see the contri- butions of Valerie Plave Bennett, Jean Leca, Helen Desfosses and J. Dirck Stryker, Jon Kraus and Frances Hill in Helen Desfosses and Jacques Levesque, eds., Socialism in the Third World (New York: Praeger, 1975), pp. 99-251. For critical analyses of the political economies of Ghana and Tanzania see the essays by Emi ly Card and Lionel Cl i ffe in Ri chard Harris, ed. , The Pol i tical Economy of Africa (Cambridge, Mass. : Schenkman, 1975) pp. 49-91 and 137-185. Arthur Jay Klinghoffer, "The Soviet Union and Africa," in Kanet, ed., The Soviet Union and the Developinq Nations, p. 63. 95 Ibid., pp. 51-77. In general, however, this essay is an unfortunate, polemical attack reminiscent of the cold war period. Klinghoffer as- serts, for instance, that "a class analysis of African society is not particulary insightful ," p. 76 and that "Africa may become anti-west- ernized and socialized, but it is unlikely to become sovietized or com- munized," p. 77. 96 Ibid., p. 51. Cf. the "Cold War" perspectives of W.A.C. Adie, Oil. Poli- tics and Seapower: The Indian ocean vortex (New York: crane; ~ussak for National Strategy Information Center, 1975). 97 Hall and Peyman, The Great Uhuru Railway, p. 13. See Catherine Hoskyns, o~ia-Somalia-Kenya Dis Press for IDA, 1969); Africa (Cambridge: Ha 245; and Colin Lequm a Rex Col 1 i ngs , 1977). rvard Uni vers in African Diplomacy: 2, The Ethi- (Dar es Salaam: Oxford University The Boundary Pol i ti cs of ~ndependent ity Press, 1972), especially pp. 212- nd Bill Lee, Conflict in the Horn of ~frica 99 See J. Bowyer Be1 1 , The Horn of Africa (New York: Crane, Russak for National Strategy Information Center, 1973) ; John H. Spencer, Ethiopia, the Horn of Africa, and U.S. Policy (Cambridge: Institute for Foreign Policy Analysis, 1977); and Legurn and Lee, Conflict in the Horn of Africa. 100 External interests become more complex and indirect if one takes into account Soviet interests in Libya, Yemen and Iraq and American support of Saudi Arabia, the Gulf states and Iran, a11 of which are involved in wider Red Sea and Indian Ocean issues. See Timothy M. Shaw, "Inequalities and Interdependence in Africa and Latin America: Sub-Imperial ism and Semi- Industri a1 i zation in the Semi -Periphery," paper presented at a meeti ng of the African Studies Association, Houston, 1977. 101 Tom J. Farer, War Clouds on the Horn of Africa: A Crisis for Detente (Washington D.C.: Carnegie Endowment, 1976), p. 153. 102 Richard Harris, "The Political Economy of Africa" in his, The Political Economy of Africa, p. 13. On the complex relations among "rnaldeveloped"/ "overdeveloped" states and poor countries, see K. J. Hol sti , "Underdevelop- ment and the 'Gap' Theory of International Confl ict ," American Pol i tical Science Review 69 (September 1975) : 827-839. 103 Soviet scholars recognize the uneven relations among the states of Africa and between Europe and Africa but they assert that Soviet-African ties can only advance African development. See Peter Foge Jensen, Soviet Research on Africa with Special Reference to International Relations, Research Report, no. 19 (Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1973). 104 On the problems of involuntary and unequal regional integration among socialist as well as capitalist states see Richard A. Fa1 k, "Zone I1 as a World Order Construct," in James N. Rosenau, Vincent Davis, Maurice A. East, eds., The Analysis of International Politics (New York: Free Press, 1972), pp. 187-206. Cf. V. G. Solodovnikov and V. Boooslovskv Non-caoi- ta1 ist Development: An Historical Out1 ine (Moscow: 6rogress; -* Developing Countries on the Non-Capi tal ist Road (Sofia: Bulgarian Academy of Sciences, 1974) and Mai Palmberq "Literature on Non-Capi tal ist Develop- ment," Scandinavian Seminar on ~on-ta~i i st Development in Africa, Hel- sinki, August 1976. Gleb Starushenko, Africa Makes a Choice: The Development of Socialist- Oriented States (Moscow: Novosti, 1975), p. 8. See also Joe Slovo, "A Cri tical Appraisal of the Non-Capi tal i st Path and the National Democratic State in Africa," Marxism ~oda~,'June pp. 1-14. For a broader discussion of alternative development strategies and their advocates see Timothy M. Shaw and Malcolm J. Grieve, "Dependence or Develop- ment? A Review Article on International and Internal Inequalities in Africa," Development and Change 8 (July 1977) : 377-408. On this strategy see What Now? Another Development (Uppsala: Dag Ham- marskjold Report, 1975), pp. 70-87. On the ecological imperative in Africa see Timothy M. Shaw and Malcolm J. Grieve, "Africa and the Envi ronmen t : The Pol i ti cal Economy of Resources, " paper presented at a meeting of the Canadian Association of African Studies, Sherbrooke, May 1976. On the problems which instabil i ty cause for the coherence and continuity of African foreign pol i cies see Richard Vengroff, "Ins tabi 1 i ty and Foreign Policy Behavior: Black Africa in the UN," American Journal of Political Science 20 (August 1976): 425-438. See R. Cranford Pratt, "Foreign-Pol icy Issues and the Emergence of Social ism Contrast the di fferent trends and explanations advanced in Andrew M. Kamarck, "Sub-Saharan Africa in the 1980's: An Economic Profile" with Phillipe Lemaitre, "Who Will rule Africa by the Year 2000?" in Helen Kitchen, ed., Africa: From Wstery to Maze (Lexington: Heath, 1976), pp. 167-194 and 249-276. For an intriguing, but essentially orthodox, comparati ve analysis of pol i tical strategies of oppression and stabi 1 i ty in Africa see also James J. Lawler, "Confl ict-Avoidance in Africa," Peace Research Reviews 8 (June 1976). See Nelson Kasfir, The Shrinking Political Arena: Participation and Ethnicity in African Politics, with a Case Study of Uganda (~erkeley: University of Cal ifornia Press, 1976), pp. 14-27 and Samuel T. Huntinqton and Joan M. Nelson, No Easy Choice: Political Participation in eve lo^- ing Countries (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1976). Cf. recent writings in the tradition of the established paradigm, for example, Arthur Jay Kl inghoffer, "Modernization and Pol i ti cal Development in Africa," Journal of Modern African Studies I1 (March 1973) : 1-19 and Leslie Rubin and Brian Weinstein, Introduction to African Politics: A Conti nen tal Approach (New York: Praeger, 1974). 114 On the pathos of the Fourth World see Gerald K. Helleiner, "The Least Developed in the New International Economic Order: Devil Take the Hind- most?" Cooperation Canada 25 (1976) : 3-1 3 and Shaw, "The Third World and the New International Order." 115 For a survey of some predictions see Timothy M. Shaw and Malcolm J. Grieve, "The Pol i tical Economy of Resources: Africa's Future in the Global En- vironment, " African Review (Forthcoming). For a review of Africa's impact on North-South bargaining see John P. Renniger, "After the Seventh Special General Assembly Session: Africa and the New Emerging World Order," African Studies Review 19 (September 1976) : 35-48. 116 On the concentration of power and infl uence on the continent see David H. Johns, "Diplomatic Activity, Power and Integration in Africa" in Patrick J. McGowan, ed., Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Policy Studies 3 (1976): 85-105. See also his "The Normalization of Intra-African Diplo- matic Acti vi ty ," Journal of Modern African Studies 10 (December 1972) : 597-610 and Timothy M. Shaw, "The Development of International Systems in Africa," a paper presented at the third International Congress of Africanists, Addis Ababa, December 1973. 11 7 Cf. A1 i A Mazrui , "The New Interdependence: From Hierarchy to Symnetry" i n Guy F. Erb and Valerina ~allab,' eds., Beyond ~e~endenc~ eve loping World Speaks Out (Washington: Overseas Development Council , 1975), pp. 38- 54. REG IOi4AL RELATIONS IN SOUTHERN AFRICA AND THE GLOBAL POLITICAL ECONOYY Kenneth W. Grundy, Case Western Reserve University It is irnpossi bl e to understand international relations in a dependent region of the world (or for that matter domestic politics in their broadest out1 ine) outside of the context of the total global constel lation of wealth and power. The imnediate purpose of this chapter is to discuss the nature of international relations in Southern Africa and the place of the region in the international political system. Differing perceptions of which state is dominant in the region, if one includes nonregional powers, of what forces determine dominance, and of what effects these factors have on the global distribution of power have made debatable what, on the surface, had once looked to be rather clear cut. Conditions of dominance and submission, super and subordination, imposition, penetration, accommodation and resi s- tance characterize regional and global affai rs regarding Southern Africa. It is our task here to sort out these relationships in systematic terms. The first part of the essay consists of some wide-ranging impressions of the structural character of the dependent pol i tical-economic relations between the developed and the less developed world. Near the end of that part we shall focus particularly on the impact of intermediary forces in the struc- tures and techniques of dependence. In the second section, we home in on Southern Africa, and especially on the pivotal place of South African settler colonialism in the region.l This is followed by a descriptive section provid- i ng a picture of contemporary regional relations. An analysis of the most current events provides the substance of the last part of the essay as we seek to establ ish whether the region is becoming unglued. We move, in short, from the general to the specific, to provide the reader with an analytical and i nterpreti ve framework by which "new" events and developments can be understood. The Structural Character of World Politics - Economic Relations The world's states are monstrously unequal in wealth, strength, size and any number of other criteria relating to general living conditions and the relative ability to make autonomous decisions and to carry our pol icies relating to these conditions. Just as importantly, within these states there is an unequal distribution of the assets of power and living conditions. In rough terms, the world is composed of "have" and "have not" states that are, in turn, made up of "have" and "have not" groups of people. Too many theories of inter- national relations and of imperial ism in particular ignore the i ntra-state features of inter-state relationships. They tend to deal with states as holistic entities. Since data usually is compiled on a statewide basis, the state often by default becomes the effective unit of analysis. Seen from one perspective, the international system consists of core (powerful ) and periphery (weak or marginal) states. The core states occupy dominant positions in the global economic systems, possess dominant or near dominant mi 1 i tary structures global in scope, and boast comnanding techno- logical and cultural structures. The periphery states are those that must, for various reasons, adjust and adapt to decisions and structures controlled by the core. Each state is 1 ikewise made up of a center (the power wielders) and a fringe (the objects of power). Depending on the issue to be decided the center consists of the political and economic elites that can at any given time expect or see to it that their wishes will be honored. The fringe includes the workers, small farmers, the unemployed, the uneducated and general ly those disadvantaged. It is because of the inequities in the distribution of the assets of power and wealth, and because of a widespread resistance to any given pattern of distribution that dominance relationships are asserted and reinforced by structural arrangements. To be sure, this introductory statement overlooks various intermediary actors, both within and between states. In addition, because of its crudity, it underplays divisions and competi tion among groups within the "have" and "have-not" elements of a state. But we shall return to these concerns shortly. There is also the danger that this type of analysis may take on the flavor of a conspiratorial theory. Nothing like this is intended. Rather, it is fully understandable that people should want to increase their material we1 1-being and their sense of personal worth and security, and to do so in concert with others with similar values and interests. They would, for obvious reasons, be more likely to appreciate their own interests and more willing to take risks to protect and improve them, at the expense of others, especially when 1 imi ted resources are being contested. Such a perspective hardly qua1 ifies as a conspiratorial theory of political behavior, although it does not imnunize political actors or their policies from criticism based on moral arguments. There is also the danger, particularly in discussing the centers and fringes of states, to infer that behavior is generally planned, just because struc- tures exist that indicate regular patterns of interaction. Again, this would be reading too much into descriptive impressions that may appear to indicate stability and continuity. To freeze a descriptive model in this fashion would be to deprive it of much of its analytical utility. Although many of the terms and metaphors used in the following discussion derive from economics, it should be made clear at the outset that dependence as used here is not strictly an economic phenomenon. On the contrary, it is an aggregate phenomenon consisting of economic, political, strateoic and cul- tural determinants and aspects. Words like asset, benefit, loss, cost, ex- change, market, 1 iabil i ty and interest, for example, should be considered in their broadest, figurative context. Though it may be useful at times to conceive of a form of domestic de- pendence (e.g., the "homelands" policy of South Africa), since our chief con- cern in this chapter is international relations, we will regard dependence as a dominance relationship between states, and one that, in its contemporary form, depends upon super and subordination within state boundaries .2 When domestic dominance patterns weaken, external governments and organi zations some- times find it necessary to construct new structures to serve as their agents or points of penetration, and to facilitate the process of unequal exchange. Thus, dependence is founded on the symbiotic, a1 though by no means equal , relationships that have been established between the center of the core state and the center of the periphery state. Both centers profit from this relation- ship; however, the center of the core profits more. The fringe elements of both states are disadvantaged by the relationship, but the fringe of the periphery state suffers more. Contemporary imperial i sts, a1 though they may not have created them, exploit these internal inequal i ties and fortui tiously encourage them by establ i shing harmonies of interest between center elements in different states, and conflicts of interest between the fringe segments in various states, between the center elements and the fringe elements in each state, and, ultimately, between the core and the periphery states themselves. It is this final antagonism, the disharmony of interests between the core and the periphery states, that is the usual subject of analysis in most studies of dependence and international relations. But this is, in many ways, only the formal manifestation of the subject. It is a symptom of the phenomenon of dependence, not i ts cause. The major potential source of instability in the system is the fringe in the periphery, for it consists of those most disadvantaged. If ever the two fringes should realize the similarity of their interests and if fringe a1 1 iances should be formed, the two centers would have to resort to more direct forms of violence to secure the imperial system. Core states have often found it necessary to rush to the rescue of periphery governments. This is as much an indication of the incomplete or inefficient operation of a complex, jerry- built contemporary dependence system as it is an indication of imperialism in full flower. Dominant states and their allies (the center of the periphery states) are willing and able to revert to the direct use of violence to sustain the status quo and their privileges within it. This implies that systemic structures work imperfectly. Stratified relationships are not solely a product of particular economic or ideological systems. Although some economic or ideological modes may be more adaptable to dominance and dependence, no single world economic system has a monopoly on imperialistic behavior and none can exclude its own behavior from being designated as imperial when it involves super and subordination reinforced by structural ties. What matters is the character and quality of the re1 ationships between states and between groups therein, and the effects these re1 ationships have on various peoples. In essence, dependence re1 ationships are exchange relationships. Whether the exchange between the core and the periphery is economic, political , rnili tary or cu! tural , the relationship is asymetrical . The character of the relation- ship is one that usually redounds to the benefit of the core at the expense of the periphery, particularly to the fringe groups of the periphery. This is not to say that all such relationships between core and periphery always work to the advantage of one side over the other. But it is normally an unequal exchange chiefly because the val ue of goods exchanged is inequitable between the actors, that is, the values exchanged have little relationship to the human efforts involved in creating the goods, or because the effects or spinoffs within the respective actors are asymnetrical. It is also unequal because the market in which the exchange occurs is controlled by the core, and hence is stacked in the core's favor. k'ith regard to the asymnetry of spinoffs, the social imp1 ications of the relationship are, on balance, disadvantageous to the periphery state and particularly to its inhabitants. Even should prices for goods exchanged be increased to the advantage of the periphery state, the effects of the relationship within the periphery state would still be negative if its social spinoffs yielded depleted resources, continued dependence on finished products manufactured in core states, di storted economic and social infrastructures, and a society that displays marginal ski1 1 s, a psychological sense of i nferiori ty and dependence, and the mai ntenance of a pri vi leged center in league with the center of a core state. In such a situation, the periphery is poorly equipped to resist the pressures and blandishments of the core. 3 The consequences of these exchanges eventual ly have pol i tical overtones which give the core immense leverage in dictating future relations. Dependence is a matter of degree. Some states and groups are more or less dependent than others, and more or less involved in the system, depend- ing on the inequalities of exchange, and the structural stabilities that under- lie their behavior. There is even the possibility and the likelihood that as condi tions constantly change, some state 's behavior may simul taneously ref1 ect characteristics of both the core and the periphery. Portugal, for example, had been dominant in the context of its own colonial system at the same time that i t was part of the periphery of a North American-West European economic sys The governments of some periphery states may perceive that their role in the larger system is to serve as an intermediary between the core and other, still more marginal states. This role may be particularly lucrative if, for one reason or another, (e.g., the existence of more than one empire, the division of labor and levels of status in the productive process, or the complications of ideological, ethnic, racial or geopol i tical factors), there is increased room for maneuver in the interstices between systems and between components of the systems. It is to such a1 ternatives that we now turn. Despite the possi bi 1 i ties or tendencies for powerful forces to concert in defense of the global order, the facts that there are different and compet- ing core powers, that within the centers of core states there are conflicts of interests, and that each element's principal concern is to maximize its particular advantages, not just in relation to the periphery but, if need be, in relation to the other core actors, do provide elements of the centers in the periphery states (and the fringes in the core and periphery) with opportunities for maneuver. 5 One might pursue this still further by noting that some geopolitical factors (location, topology and the uneven distribution of the worl d's scarce resources) might also be parlayed into the rise of intermediary forces. Given ideological bl indspots and racial and ethnic hang-ups, additional flexibi 1 i ties and rigid- ities are introduced into an already complex system. The effect is to provide interstices in which ostensibly less powerful states can find space to provide intermediary services to more powerful actors in the system. The price exacted for these services is enhanced stature and influence and even a competi tive role within the system. At the same time an intermediary state may issist the imperialists on other issues. It may even go so far as to construct an embryonic mini-empi re in its own right, usual ly, however, with the encouragement or at least acquiescence of core gr0u~s.6 This mini-empire, far from being an object of derision and scorn, may eventually challenge a larger core state, at first in regional terms (perhaps beginning with only a single issue) and then, conceivably in even broader terms. This would be the case particularly if it could exploit its own hinterland more efficiently than it was being ex- ploi ted by the dominant core. Just as a strict dichotomy between center and fringe is too crude for social analysis at the intra-state level, so the distinction between core and periphery must be hedged with reservations, ex- ceptions, qua1 ifications and contingencies in trying to understand the workings of the international system. In a world of some 150 states, it stands to reason that there is room for at least a few such intermediary actors. Southern Africa and Settler Colonial ism South Africa displays many of the characteristics of an intermediary state. The South African economy, partially industrialized and partially a producer of primary products and raw materials, might be said to be one or two steps ahead of most periphery states in the productive ladder, yet still a couple of steps behind core states. South Africa imports unskilled 1 abor from its 1 ess developed nei ghbors , yet i t sti 11 depends heavily on products and technology emanating from the core. It exports finished pro- ducts and to a much lesser extent investment capital to its neighbors, yet must still secure capital and reinvested profits and sell its raw materials to more advanced economies. It is, in short, located in the middle of the production process, and hence, in between the core and periphery in the global system. This has led to a rather ambiguous combination of foreign and domes- tic policies, some of which reflect a harmony of interest between South Africa and the imperialist core, and some of which reflect conflicts of interest and competition with the core. But that it is part of the dependence system, a crucial link in the productive and control chain, is undeniable. South Africa and to a far lesser extent, Rhodesia occupy intermediary places in the Euro-American global system for another reason, too, one that under1 i es how and why they managed to achieve thei r role of economi c mi ddl e- ranking. This reason related directly to the peculiarities of their own centers, for a crucial intermediary force in the dependence system has been colonial-settlers, especially when they are able to establish minority regimes. The term colonial-settler, as used here, must include not only settlers, but a1 1 the administrative machinery associated with the expatriate mercantile- extractive complex -- the local staffs of metropol i tan-based companies, the colonial civil service at the lower (less mobile) grades, and the agents and backers of these interests in the metropolitan core. This group has emerged as a "third element", an "independent factor" insinuating itself between the core governments and the i ndi genous peopl es of periphery states .7 By asserting their independence, colonial-settler governments may both strengthen and chal lenge the establ ished imperial i st order. How and why do such colonial-settler elites come to be relatively inde- pendent? To answer this we have to look into the history of colonial expansion. Without raising the important question of what propel led or initiated the nineteenth century imperialist thrust, it is necessary to admit that one seminal factor was the colonial-settlers themselves. They came in most in- stances from the mother country and often were the direct administrative agents of the metropol itan government and of companies based in and financed by capital frov the metropole. Nevertheless, there was never a precise coincidence of interests between this colonial element and the government in the metropol is. Because of the structural evolution of modern imperial ism, a point was reached at which the core's center decided that direct administration of colonial ter- ri tories did not add to the advantages derived from a territory in relation to the costs involved. Imperialist governments realized that it was not necessary, indeed in certain contexts actually detrimental, to be saddled with the responsibilities, costs and stigma of being a colonial power. This was not a unilateral decision. Domestic and international pressures, pl us the increased costs of colonial government resul ting from national ist independence pressures in the colonies contributed to such policy decisions. But it was determined that old advantaqes might actually be more effectively maintained and managed by an indigenous "self- governing" elite tied to the ex-metropole by other, non-official 1 inks. In contrast, at some different point in the evolution of the colony, some colonial-settlers began to realize that: (1) they could benefit to a greater extent if they were to sever or at least re-arrange their links with the me- tropole; and/or (2) ul timate self-government for the fringe majority (and even for an indigenous elite tied to the ex-metropole) might jeopardize the colonial- settlers' preferred position in the colony. Hence, it becam clear that their own interests conflicted with those of their mother country, or at least with the governing elements there. This left them with basically three a1 ternatives. In order of probable preference to the colonial-settlers these were: (1 ) inde- pendence with government in the hands of the colonial-settlers, usually a minority government except in cases of the earlier classical colonies; (2) con- tinued colonial rule with the colonial-settlers in legal surrogate but still privileged positions ; or (3) independence under an indigenous government. It was possible, a1 though risky, to attempt a fourth a1 ternative, somewhere be- tween alternatives two and three, that is, to create an airtight alliance with key elements of the indigenous elite and support their bid to independence. This is not unlike the way that the colonial-settlers in Katanga (Shaba) cham- pioned Moi se Tshornbe. But this provided 1 ittler security since, ultimately, both the imperial powers and the indigenous majority would seek to annul this marriage of convenience. It is wrong, therefore, bl indly to regard colonial- settlers as nothing but spokesman for the imperial core state. Thus, the presence and pressures of the colonial-settlers may help ex- plain why some imperial powers have been unwilling or have had a difficult time divesting themselves of certain territories. ' The colonial-settlers themselves and their allies and agents in the metropole proved to be a tenacious and formi dab1 e pol i tical force in metropol i tan pol i ti cs. Thei ;* 1 i ves were meaningless outside of their own portion of empire. They benefited directly from their colony. Therefore, they promoted their colony. Ironically, this is why they were sometimes found opposing the core's center when decisions of emi>i re were in the balance. They chal len~ed mother country whenever it appeared that the latter was making policy based upon considerations of the wider, total empi re. No matter how paradoxical this may appear, it is con- ceivable and 1 i kely that the contemporary imperial relationship (i .e., the unequal exchange relationship) no longer needs colonial-settlers. Hence, empire might actually be advanced by policies that on the surface seem to represent a retreat from formal or juridical empire. This has been an era when the formal institutional trappings of empire are a liability. Because colonial-settlers' horizons are 1 imi ted or because thei r fie1 d of maneuver is provincial, not global, colonial-settlers resist their "sell-out" by pur- suing what they try to promote as "anti-imperial" policies that are in their imnediate interest, but in conflict with the long-run interests as conceived by the core's center.8 They become, in short, anti-imperialists in the global context in order to facilitate, prolong and strengthen their own domestic "imperial" system. The colonial-settlers, then, come to be a middle force, exploi ti ng and denigrating the indigenous territorial or regional population, slowing down the process of independence for an indigenous government, and also, occasional ly, resisting the pol icies of the great corporations and their governmental spokesmen back in the metropole. Settler comnuni ties, unl i ke the big capitalist enterprises, have by and large been unable to come to terms with even the indigenous elite. Only by seceding from the empire could the colonial settlers be free to repress and exploit more completely the majority fringe in their territories, the element that to them represents the greatest threat. It appeared, with South Africa's outward policy, dialogue about dialogue, and detente, that South Africa's leaders were ready to accommodate themselves to bourgeois black regimes on their boundaries. But there are built- in limits as to how flexible they can be. The core's center and especially the core's fringe do not easily abandon their colonial settlers. Racial attachments, family and psychological ties of "kith and kin" do not evaporate on signal. For these reasons the abandon- ment is seldom total, and may in fact only take place on one level, the govern- mental. South Africa's complexities, with racial affinities confused by Afri kaner against English-speaker in turn further baffled by class sympathies and identi ties, prompted the Afrikaner government to regard Great Britain not as the mother country but as the imperial enemy. But there were also powerful British- rooted economic interests in turn-of-the-century South Africa that saw an opportunity to enlarge profits if they could involve the British govern- ment and military in their own cause. Britain "won" the ensuing Boer War but "lost" the peace. Whi le the British and Engl ish-speaking South Africans took firm hold of the economy the political system was turned back to the ~frikaners.~ Boer against Great Britain is an unusual case because of the national istic split that accounted for important economic contradictions among the colonial -settlers in South Africa. Far more frequently col onial-settlers derive from the metropole itself, and usually are only a generation or two or three removed from the "home country". In Rhodesia, A1 geria, Kenya, Angola, Mozambique and Katanga this has been the case. Race and ethnicity are convenient code groupings that may, of course, be raised to the level of causal factors, as in South Africa. But they are reinforced and made important because of the economic and political ramifications they entail. As the colonial-settler comnuni ty took root it began to establish insti- tutions and interests that, depending on their size and character, became increasingly independent of the metropole. Even nominally metropolitan insti- tutions displayed fissiparous tendencies. It did not take colonial officials in the territory long to realize that only one thing stood between them and uninhibited power, the metropol i tan government. So they began with appeals for more decisional latitude, followed them with arguments for the efficiency and " democracy" of greater decen tral i zation and terri torial autonomy, and ended up with demands for and finally declarations of independence. The speed with which this process moved depended on a number of factors, not the least of which were the degree to which the administrative machinery depended on metro- pol itan revenues and military might to assure their station, the extent of settler pressure behind them, and the determination of the metropol i tan government to resist such trends. Settler colonies were more inclined to move along this road than purely administrative colonies. If colonial settlers felt that they might add to their economic privileges as we1 1 as their power by moving away from the mother country, they did not hesitate, arguing as did the Rhodesians, that it was the mother country that disowned them, not the other way around? Li!:ewise, settler employees and officials of metropol i tan-based entwprises also manifested independent tendencies, especially if they reasoned that their local operations were self-sufficient and could compete in the total world economy and that they might thereby inflate their psychological and material rewards by assuming total control rather than exercising subordinate admini- strative roles. Moreover, other fully or principal ly local enterprises were competitors of metropolitan interests, and hence suffered from ultimate author- ity being in the hands of the core's center. They were not especially sym- pathetic to the interests of the imperial whole. Indeed, since they were anxious to maximi ze their immediate advantages by exploiting the indigenous labor pool more ruthlessly, they constituted the most aggressive segment of the colonial-settler opponents of continued imperial rule. In some African colonies, for various reasons, the imperial power allied, a1 bei t not always enthusiastically, with the indigenous bourgeois national ists whom they regarded as the best bet to prolong the imperial pattern of unequal relationships without the albatross of juridical empire. No force in t+e issue supported the indigenous masses. In some cases, the hasty retreat from legalistic colonialism can be explained by a desire on the part of imperial decision makers to move before the colonial settlers could consolidate their positions and snatch independence for themselves. It was not an altruistic desire to a1 low majorities to be self-governing. Rather, legal istic decoloni- zation was simply an evidence of long-term flexibility. There was the danger that racial minority regimes in former colonies were unstable and increasingly independent of the former metropole. The core's center had a1 ready chosen the indigenous bourgeois bureaucrats to rep1 ace the often irascible, some- times demanding, potentially independent colonial-settler officials. The process frequently led to the colonial-settler regime being ostracized as a pariah by neighbors and often the wider global community. By thus being isolated the regime gains added incentive to solidify its independence by pursuing autarchic pol icies designed to make it economically and mi 1 i tarily sel f-sufficient. There is, of course, no reason why at some point indigenous bureaucrats cannot reason as do the colonial-settlers. In the future they too may begin to think that they possess the skills and resources to "go it alone", and by so doing avoid the necessity of sharing power and profit with metropolitan i nteres ts . In addi ti on, thei r own domes tic pol i tical i nsecuri ty may compel them at least to appear to break with the core states. This would require that they somehow transcend a dependent colonial mentality that had been carefully cultivated by imperial experience. This is not impossible, however, to some extent it has a1 ready occurred in some territories, as in Tanzania. In most cases the relationship between the centers of core and periphery is dynamic with each side testing the 1 irni ts of control and autonomy. However, the periphery's centers usually look upon rev01 utionary autonomy as premature or "unreal istic". Indicators as to why the imperial powers oppose the independence of colon- ial settler governments might be found in the policies that these governments followed once they secured juridical independence. The case of South Africa and, a1 though the time factor makes this difficult, the case of Rhodesia, are instructive. South Africa, for example, has moved in the past thirty years from a state almost entirely dependent on economic and other ties with the former metropole to one that, a1 though still dependent on core economic forces, has learned to exploit these relationships more fully. In so doing South Africa, not the ex-metropole, has begcn to define the terms of contact. It, more than the ex-metropole, has begun to exercise regional economic hegemony, and it is being re-integrated into the global capitalist system on far more favorabl e terms. Wi thout reviewing the economic evol ution and most notably the industrial i- zation of South Africa, we can appreciate that the government in Pretoria today defines the terms of foreign investment and trade in that country. In the past South Africa had been principally a supplier of gold and raw materials for European and North American finance and industry. But its gov- ernment has taken conscious steps to reshape this relationship of dependency. By creating governmental corporations, especially in "vulnerable" and strate- gi cal ly important economic and mi 1 i tary sectors, by investing in infrastructure, by direct government investment in forei gn-based private firms, by requiring sales of stock locally, by forcing or encouraging foreign capital to accept i ncreasing degrees of local participating and control, by forcing industrial i- zation through regulations demanding increased local content of products as- sembled in South Africa, and by redefining the terms of trade with other core countries through adjustments in tariff and 1 icensing policies, South Africa has asserted its independence of Great ~ritain.11 The result has been not only a consol idation of the instruments of domestic colonialisla, but the creation of a South African imperial ism of its own.12 The South African govern- ment has not only dominated key sectors of the economy, but it has "domesticated" many that, in the context of other countries, had been heretofore fairly rapacious and sel f-con tai ned forei gn enterprises. One gets the impression that there has not been much resistance from executives and directors in the core, largely because this enables them to plead innocence regarding apartheid social pol icies that they have not really tried to change or modify, and from which they profit.13 An attitude of self- imposed isolation growing out of South Africa's inability to deal with external and internal cri ticism and ostracism, combined with regional strategic vul- nerabil i ty, contributed to this pol icy direction. External and internal threat were real enough to harden their resolve to maximize their defensibil i ty, independence and autarky. All of this is not to argue that the Republic of South Africa is a totally independent entity in world politics, divorced from the wider capitalist econo- mic system. It is sufficient, however, to give rise to discussion as t3 whether, at least in terms of Southern Africa, the South African tail is wagging the U.K. dog, or at least is doing pretty much as it pleases without much more than verbal resistance from U. K. or U.S. governments and investors.14 Since peripheral relationships are a matter of degree, it must be admitted that South Africa is significantly more independent of Great Britain today that twenty-fi ve years ago, and considerably more than most ostensibly "independent" former colonies. Moreover, a1 though today there is more contact between various European capital ist interests and their South African counterparts, it must be added that what is vital in exploring imperial relationships is not solely the extent or volume of these 1 inks, but their qua1 itative nature, in terms of super and subordination. To be sure, extensive linkages can contribute to the perception and the reality of dependence. But in itself it is not explanatory. The more important questions relate to the character of those relationships and the extent of their inequality. Who benefits and who loses and to what extent? Certainly there is a great deal more trade between the United States and Europe than there is between the Uni ted States and Latin America. But i n one case the effect of that trade yields dominance and dependence; in the other case, the relationship is more debatable. The same might be noted with regard to investments, technical exchanges, cul tural and comnunications contacts and political ties. Or take the case of South Africa. Less than eight per cent of its trade is with Africa, but the asymmetry 1 ies essentially in its favor. In contrast about seventy per cent of its trade is directed to Europe and America. In the latter arrangement, however, the relationships are considerably more equitable. Structurally the spin-offs sti 11 benefit the industrial states and the center of the intermediary state. Hence volume and quality (in monetary and structural terms) must be considered in any analytical equation. It is not enough to argue that since return on investment is higher in South Africa than practical ly anywhere else in the Comnonweal th, then Bri ti sh and American capital is exploiting South Africa. Rather the better argument is that out- side investors are exploiting the indigenous population (the fringe) and the natural resources of South Africa, but so is the colonial settler minority, even to a greater degree. Exploitation, it must be remembered, is not a zero- sum game. One side's gains do not necessarily cancel out the other party's losses. Rather certain organizational and structural changes may inflate the sum total of gains, rendering exploitation no less real, but nevertheless a1 tering the rnagni tude and character of the relationships. The apartheid policies of the South African regime have rendered a situation where there is more than enough for the centers in both the core and the intermediary. Some of the excess may be distributed to the fringe in the core -- almost none goes to the indigenous fringe in Southern Africa. Hence it is not so much that the colonial settlers are against finance imperial ism in principle. Rather, there seems to be a kind of love-hate relationship founded on a con- fl icting yet complementary economic ~artnership a positive community of security interests. The core suppl ies the capital , the technology, the trade, the long-term protection and strategic support and the ideological legi timi- zation in the world at large, and the center of the intermediary state provides the pol i tical structure for control 1 ing and exploiting indigenous labor, access to the raw materials and the ruthlessness and muscle to maintain local order. They need one another, but they still do not trust one another, since each can concei ve of arrangements that might be preferable, and even more profitable to itself. The decisional center of gravity has been shifted by determined and conscious governmental pol icy by the center of the intermediary state. Insofar as profits continue to flow to the core's center, new investments (which in most cases are re-i nvestrnents of local ly generated profits) and increased trade will accrue to South Africa. But the structural instruments for greater independence from the core a,re being established despite and because of the extension of these contacts. South Africa's relations with the core are in an important transitional state. Its governing elite senses this. Earlier, South Africa's leaders sug- gested that they might serve as "bridges" between black Africa and ~uro~e.15 But later views became more assertive and independent of Europe. As the African states were about to be granted formal independence, Foreign Minister Louw gratuitously warned African statesmen of the danqers of dealinq with Eurooe. He spoke of "sel f-appointed advi sors" from "outsi de" who sought only profit for themselves and the countries that sent them. Moreover, he cited the dangers of "foreign financiers" seeking valuable concessions and guaranteed profits. Finally, he told them that with foreign aid "a political quid pro quo will be demanded (or at least expected)." Not bad advice, and coming from one whose people, earlier in its history suffered some of these same imperial machinations. He clearly meant the European powers, but latter-day warnings have substituted the spectre of communist rather than European capitalist imperialism. Louw's words might well have served as early caution regarding South Africa's "outward looking" policy. Later Pretoria became fully aware of the opportunities that its growing economi c power affords i t in black Africa. !dhi te South Africans draw the parallels between their role in the rest of Africa and the United States' domination of the Americas. Insofar as this could be real ized the result would be an intense struggle between EuroAmerican interests and those of South Africa for hegemony in Southern Africa. It has already begun in some places, such as Malawi, Rhodesia and the former High Commission Territories, to the extent that the indigenous governments permit and encourage i t. But though South Africa is anxious to assert its i ndepen- dence of Europe and America in economic terms, it is sti 11 keen on fa1 1 ing back on these powers as strategic elements in the global contest, and even in the regional contest, especially since the tenuous balance of forces has been a1 tered. Even though the control mechanisms may be slipping from the hands of the ruling elements in the metropole, the new relationships are so lucrative as to neutralize some core protest and resistance and to produce acquiescence i f not enthusiastic coll aboration from various el i tes, notwithstanding sporadic pub1 ic outcries of righteous indignation. But the structural changes are central . Much current discussion of imperialism flows from the common sense pro- position that whoever pays the piper calls the tune. Things are not that simple in practice. We have arrived at a situation in Southern Africa (and elsewhere, too) where there i s a wi deni ng "non-correspondence between the na- tional i ty of capital and the national i ty of effecti ve state power. "16 For example, the core may be prevented, because of domestic political problems or external pressures and risks, from applying full mi 1 i tary and financial power everywhere. Even should this be attempted, success is not guaranteed. Hence, in regional affairs the core may, by necessity, defer to governments that on one hand may appear to be junior partners but on sow questions effectively become equal or even senior partners. South Africa had been carving out such a relationship before the Portuguese fall and the growing effectiveness of black revolutionary forces in the region forced the core to search for newer arrange- ments. We have presented an overview of relations in Southern Africa. It remains to describe current aspects of regional relationships in order to analyze and interpret events as they unfol d. Contemporary Regional Re1 ati ons The economic might of the Republic of South Africa (RSA) continues to cast a shadow over the entire region and the spectre of South Africa's armed forces hovers nearby. In many ways white South Africa is both the glue holding the region together as an embyonic economic unit and the irritant that might precipitate its di smemberment. South Africa produces si xty-six per cent of the region's gross domestic product. Virtual ly a1 1 economic indicators (in colonial times) and the basic economic infrastructure reinforced this situation. Transport routes, vol untary and recruited migratory labor flows, the economic and geopol i tical ramifications of being land-locked, electrical grids and transfers of technology and investment served to strengthen the dominance relationships favoring the settler and colonial regimes, especially of South Africa and Portugal. 17 It has not been easy for leaders in independent African states to sever these 1 i nkages. Indeed, there is serious question regarding thei r commi tment to re-structure these dependent economic re1 ationshi ps , and thei r capacity to do so even if they desired. The burdens of subordination do not fall evenly on all peoples and governments. To appreciate the complex reality of uneven level s of dependency, it is necessary to review the extensity and intensity of regional 1 inkages of the specific territories concerned. South West Africa/Namibia. This territory occupies a unique position in - - - - - - -- - - - - - -- - the region.18 During World War I, South West Africa, which had been a German colony, was occupied by South African troops. This was legitimized by the Allied and Associated Powers which, under terms of the Covenant of the League of Nations, designated South West Africa a Class C Mandate to be administered by South Africa. With the demise of the League and its replacement by the United Nations, South Africa, rather than allow the UN to oversee its admini- stration of the area as a Trust Territory, approached the General Assembly for permission to incorporate the territory into the Union. The General Assembly denied this request in December 1946. Following this rebuff, South Africa continued to administer South West Africa as a part of South Africa, claiming to do so under terms of the Mandate. A1 though the General Assembly passed a resol ution in 1966 terminating South Africa's mandate, and subsequent advisory opinions of the International Court of Justice and resolutions of the General Assembly and Security Counci 1 maintain that the continued presence of South Africa in Namibia (as it is now officially designated outside of South Africa) is illegal, South Africa still rules the vast territory. South West Africa is integrally a part of the South African econonly, using the same currency, the same tariff structure, regulated from Pretoria, and with trade and productivity data being incorporated officially into com- mon statistics. But despite the apparent effective occupation and integration, there is growing evidence of popular discontent and of a reluctant South African wi 11 i ngness to readjust i ts relationship wi th the underpopulated, mineral-rich land in order to secure the success of its detente policy and its long-range stabilization as a white regime in a black continent. Nonethe- less, by a series of fortuitous (for South Africa) circumstances, the conquest and absorbtion of South West Africa represented the first success of the ex- pansive policy of the independent government in the Union of South Africa. It was a harbinger of the outward pol icy and of South Africa's budding challenge to Great Britain for control of the region. Wi th the increased i nterna ti onal pressures regardi ng Namibia, South Africa cannot continue to occupy the territory much as before. Rather South Africa is moving to moderni ze the dependency relationship. Realizing that accomno- dations must be made if South Africa is to escape being drawn into an inter- national war over Namibia, and if the white inhabitants of Namibia are to be protected and South African business interests are to continue to operate profitably in the territory, South Africa has sought to arrive at an internal settlement with various conservative ethnic interests in Narni bia. South Africa has permitted the U.N. Secretary-General and his deputies to visit Namibia where they have met with petitioners of diverse viewpoint and nationality. Real i zing as we1 1 , as did other colonial powers before i t, that i t was not imperative to administer a dependency di rectly, South Africa wants to emplant a cooperative, indeed pliable indigenous government, one that would exclude the revolutionary liberation movement (SWAPO) from participation. If SWAPO cannot be totally excluded, South Africa hopes to neutralize or isolate them in the domestic Namibian political process. At present, South Africa intends to grant independence to a racially mixed government by the end of 1978. Such a step, it is hoped, would deflect international criticisms and blunt the appeal of revolutionaries. To South Africa it is a dynamic and gradual ad- justment (they would see it as an initiative) to an already explosive and un- rnanageabl e issue. Rhodesia/Zimbabwe. On November 11 , 1965, the white minority Rhodesian Front Government declared its independence of Great Britain. After 33 years of being administered by the British South Africa Company (BSAC, Ceci 1 Rhode's concessionary corporation), Rhodesia had been annexed as a British colony in 1923. The predominantly white Rhodesian electorate on October 22, 1922, had voted 8,774 to 5,989 to reject amalgamation with the Union of South Africa in favor of responsible government under the British crown. The choice was a setback for South Africa, Britain and the BSAC, all of whom urged Rhodesians to join South Africa. But as Rhodesia grew and greater and greater resources were discovered, competition between Britain and South Africa for control mounted. Colonial status for Rhodesia gave British capital ists and settlers certain advantages over their South African counterparts. So when UDI was declared, the stage was again set for more open competition between the two powers vying for regional dominance. South Africa had the advantage of location. Its proximity plus road and rai 1 1 inks with Rhodesia were crucial. Likewise, its ports (a1 though a1 ready crowded) gave it an opportunity to help Rhodesia evade the sacction~ imposed by the UN. Rhodesian do1 lars could be exchanged for South African Rands. South African "pol ice" units (upwards of 4,000 men) bolstered the Rhodesian anti-guerril la forces.19 And South Africa's sympathetic whites and their government facilitated the 1 ife of a pariah state in an otherwise hostile world. Portugal , through its colony of Mozambique, a1 so provided simi 1 ar "services" .20 Far away Great Britain, in contrast, by the ill-chosen device of economic sanctions (the government had earlier ruled out the use of force) ,21 had virtually severed the most effective links it had with Rhodesia, i .e., cultural, trade and monetary contacts and tariff arrangements. In effect Rhodesia became for South African businessmen a capti ve market. The overall impact of the rearrangement of dependencies is that the white ninori ty regime, though conscious of its drift southward, became heavi ly dependent for the maintenance of its domination on South Africa. Mi 1 i tary, economic, strategi c and cultural contacts with South Africa expanded as those with Great Britain contracted or were severed. The result was that by around 1972 Rhodesia could be referred to figuratively as South Africa's "Sixth province" .22 Even the Zambian Foreign Minister, in explain- ing his country's dealing with South Africa to gain the peaceful liberation of a Zimbabwe and Namibia, argued that "The -- facto position is that South Africa is the colonial authority we have to deal wi th."23 Certainly, there is an important distinction between colonial status and that of a province, but the message with regard to the ultimate locus of power is clear. Nonetheless, for diverse reasons South Afri ca' s leaders have chosen to reconsider this tendency. Angola. Even though in the later years of Portuguese rule more whites (almost 500,000) resided in Angola than in any part of the region except South Africa, this territory was never especial ly close to South Africa. Infrastructural 1 inks were never developed, and trade and investment relationships were marginal. The I Cunene Ri ver scheme (hydroelectric and irrigation) , now under construction, was the first major tangible linkage southward. In fact, the British had more profound economic ties with Angola through their Portuguese connections and their investments in the Benguela railway and in various mineral and plantation developments. For the bureaucrats, business interests and the white citizens of Angola, the structural 1 i nkages of dependency headed northward through Lisbon. The Benguel a rai lway , i n turn, inflated Angola's strategic importance for the copper mines of Zaire and Zambia. Rather, Portugal (in Angola) and South Africa stood united as ideological and psychological bastions of resistance to majori ty rule and black national ism. They also collaborated in mi 1 itary-intell igence-strategic activities and reinforced one another i n Western and international forums. But the April 1974 overthrow of the Portuguese government by dissident young officers, and the ultimate rise to power of leftist elements in the armed forces changed this. After thirteen years of rev01 utionary war in three African ter- ri tories the Portuguese sought to terminate the wars by withdrawing from Africa. The coup leaders at first did not advocate a total abandonment of their terri- tories in Africa. General Antonio Spinola, who led the military junta unti 1 his forced resignation on 30 September 1974, favored a policy of continued federation or association with Angola and Mozambique in order to protect the large Portuguese minorities in these territories and to maintain the profi ta- ble economic links on which the fragile Portuguese economy depended. This, coupled with the prospects of a right-wing military coup, external manipu- 1 ations and attempted assassinations, led the younger mi 1 i tant officers in the Armed Forces Movement to force Spinola from office and into exile, and to divest Portugal (as they had originally planned) of its African holdings. The pace of decol oni zati on in Mozambique quickened, for Mozambique was blessed by the presence of only one effective African nationalist movement, the widely popular Frelimo. Angola still remained a question as no single liberation movement (the MPLA, the FNLA or UNITA) had asserted ascendancy. Col laboration among them in a transitional government, encouraged by Portugal, the OAU and by various African governments, continual ly fa1 tered. Eventually a full scale civil war erupted and in mid-1975 a coalition of FNLA (based in northern Angola and assisted by Zaire, the United States and China) and UNITA (eastern and southern based and assisted by the United States and South Africa) fought against the MPLA (supported by the Soviet Union and Cuba), entrenched in the capital and in control of many key cities, coastal regions and ports. Zaire has long dreamt of re-establ ishing the historic Congo kingdom by annexing northern Angola. A1 though such an irredenta may frighten some An- golans, it frightens them even more since it leaves unsettled the fate of Cabinda, the oil-rich enclave on the north side of the Congo River, heretofore administered as part of Angola and coveted by Zaire and others. There in late 1974 a subsidiary of Gulf Oil was lifting 300,000 barrels a day and far more in prospect. One can quickly see a possible explanation for the cooperation of Zaire and the United States with the FNLA. The MPLA's occupation of Cabinda threatens Gulf interests and thwarts Zaire's ana the FNLA's desire to secure those oi 1 revenues for themsel ves. Because of domestic unrest and indecision the Portuguese government had been unable to act in Angola. They favored the MPLA, which also seemed most effectively in control in the field. But Portugal wanted to achieve a smooth transition to self-government before independence was granted on November 11, 1975. It was difficult for them simply to cut Angola adrift before a resolution of the civil war was assured, especially in that Portugal might be effectively abandoning a large number of Portuguese still in Angola. But as the civil war became more unmanageable, Angolan whites fled the territory. By the scheduled independence of Angola in November 1975, a mass exodus left only 30,000 whites out of some 500,000 there before the coup.24 And the Portuguese armed forces, .rhich once numbered as many as 70,000, withdrew totally by independence. Angola became, for the white Portuguese, an abandoned land. Portugal 's role in the Angolan war became basically insignificant once the Armed Forces Movement let i t be known that Portugal intended to wi thdraw. Despite the MPLA's control of the capital and its heavy military assis- tance from the Soviet Union and Cuba, the FNLA with Zairian and mercenary assistance did not fold in its northern home base .25 And UNITA, in uneasy alliance with FNLA in the south, and supported by mercenary forces and South African regulars (officially set at up to 2,000 men) attached to UNITA units, slashed through southern and coastal Angola taking key cities and ports. MPLA with massive Cuban military aid repulsed this thrust and eventual ly asserted an uneasy governmental control over ~n~ola,26 UNITA still harrasses the government forces through 1 arge stretches of terri tory. South Africa, the United States, Zaire and China still dabble in Angola, as do the latter and Cuba in Zairian affairs. Mozambique. In contrast to the Angolan situation, South Africa's ties with Mozambique have been extensive, intensive and long-standing. It has been estimated that in 1971, for example, approximately forty-two per cent of Mozambique ' s GNP was deri ved from South African 1 inks .27 Particularly vi tal are South Africa's use of the port of Maputo (Lourenco Marques) for the ship- ments of the Wi twatersrand (Johannesburg and vicinity ). Mozambique a1 so se- cures the hard capital earned by her railways and ports; the per capita fees, wages, and taxes paid and col lected by South Africans for mine labor: exports to South Africa: and in the past the tourist trade generated by South Africans and Rhodesians. The supply of laborers to the Witwatersrand Native Labour Association is, by governmental agreement of 1901 and updated in 1928, tied into the use of the port of Maputo. In return for the exclusive right to contract for up to 100,000 workers per year in Mozambique, South Africa agreed to ship at least 47.5 per cent of the Transvaal 's exports and imports through the port. bre modern 1 i nkages , parti cul arly the Caborra Bassa hydroelectri c project, have intensified South African interests in continued good relations with whomever control s Mozambique and vice versa. 28 Where doubt and pessimism marked the march to independence in Angola, euphoria and optini sm characteri zed the process in Mozambique, even among some whites remaining in the country. The announcement of a new constitution set the tone. The fundamental objective of the new state would be to el imi- nate the structures of oppression and colonial exploitation, to extend and reinforce democratic popular power and, in terms of foreign affairs, to carry on "the struggle against colonialism and imperialism." In addition foreign capital would be a1 lowed to operate only within the framework of the econom- ic policy of the state. Such a course is to be followed even though other socialist countries are to be the "natural allies" of ~ozambi~ue.29 President Samora Machel, in the weeks before and after independence, fleshed out these dicta regarding Mozambique's regional pol icy, a1 though he did so with a desi re to keep as many options open as he could. He said, for example, that Mozambique was fi rmly commi tted to backing Zimbabwe national - ists in their bid for majority rule. On South Africa he has taken a less milS tant line, despite expressions of so7 idarity with the masses in South Africa and ~amibia. Rhodesia and Ian Smith are excoriated regularly in the press, but John Vorster is treated more civilly. At first, relations continued without major hitch. Until early 1978, South Africa acted as Mozambique's agent by selling on the open market the gold heretofore usually transferred to Portugal at the official rate to cover the deferred payments to Mozambican workers on the South African mines. The hard currency at windfall profits thereby gained was sent to Mozambique, one early resul t of the coup. The South African consulate general in Maputo, closed before independence, has been replaced by a visa office, a1 though the Mozambicans have not established a similar office in South Africa. On the supply of mine laborers, Frelimo Vice President Marcelino dos Santos has said, "In principle we are against recruiting workers for imperial ism. However, we must also be real istic. We cannot dssune our full responsibilities in relation to South Africa in a month or even a ~ear.1'31 But it is just this blend of principle and realism that has marked Frelirno's rule and which keeps the South Africans guessing and hopeful. Policies, by and large, have involved only moderate change. But it is the implication that changes will occur and the real meaning of the cryptic "our full responsibilities in relation to South Africa" that loom in South Africa's future. Rhodesians were even more the target of Frel imo bombast. Nonetheless, despite Britain's offer to subsidize Mozambique's losses from closing the border with Rhodesia,32 the government did not close Rhodesia's access routes by rail or road to the Indian Ocean ports of Beira and Maputo until March 1976. Since then there have been major border incursions and a virtual state of war prevails. Zambia. Before independence in 1964, Zambia 's long-standing re1 ations with the white settler regimes were intense, extensive and ambiguous. De- pendence upon transport routes southward to export copper was unti 1 recently almost complete. For example, as late as 1972 over fifty per cent of ?ambials exports went by rail through Rhodesia and almost fifty per cent of its imports came via Rhodesia. A good many Zambian businesses had been subsidiaries of Rhodesian and South African firms, or of British firms managed from regional offices in Johannesburg or Sal i sbury . Zambia's own white population (nearly 74,000 at independence, around 30,000 today), so crucial for important techni- cal and managerial skills, originated in large part in the south, or at least it had imbibed a heady slug of the social philosophy of segregation and racial supremacy from colonial settler societies. Historically, Zambia has traded heavily with Rhodesia and South Africa. In 1964, for example, some sixty per cent of Zambia's imports came from the white south, where it sold about twelve per cent of its exports. By 1975 this had been considerably reduced and South Africa had fallen to sixth place as Zambia's source of imports, mostly in the critical grain, mining and equipment sectors. The years since Zambian independence and Rhodesia ' s UDI (1 965) have seen Zambia consciously attempt to reorient its economy and cultural life away from white settler Africa. Symbol ic of the reoriented economy has been the celebrated Tanzara (the Tan-Zam Railway) which links the copper be1 t to Dar es Salaam 1860 ki lorneters away. Despite manifol d problems (changing gauges, inadequate port faci l i ties in Dar, the 1 ightness of construction that necessitates ha1 f-loaded cars), it provides Zambia with a vital a1 ternative l ifel ine and thereby increases its bargaining power with Rhodesia and South Africa. 33 In another sense Rhodesia is responsible for Zambia's abil ity to redirect its trade and transport. In January 1973, Prime Minister Smith closed the border with Zambia, hoping to force President Kaunda to stifle Zambabwean 1 i beration movement activities in Zambia. 34 Instead, the Zambians completely rejected Smith's demands and closed their side of the border. They then util ized a1 ternative routes for a1 1 shipments. Rhodesian Railways thus lost around $1,200,000 monthly in revenues from Zambia. This, coupled with hostile pol i tical measures (UN votes, sanctuary for pol i tical exiles and national ist leaders, 1 eadership in efforts to isolate minority ruled southern African regimes), have imparted a sense of independence heretofore absent from Zambian foreign pol icy. 35 Sti 11, the Zambian economy (and hence the Zambian government of Kenneth Kaunda) is in deep trouble. It is partially the old problem of unequal exchange, and of markets for primary comnodities being in the hands chiefly of the consumer corporations and countries. The demand for copper (which used to account for ninety-eight per cent of Zambia's foreign exchange earnings) is down. This has led to an extended slump in prices and a forty per cent reduction in sales. Trans- portation difficulties sti 11 exist (largely because of the warfare in Angola and border closures) and have led to the two giant mining corporations declaring a forty per cent force majeur because they have been unable to fill orders. Such developments, coupled with inflated import prices (especial ly of oi 1 ), and inefficiencies and misdirections in domestic development priorities have left Zambia wi th massi ve balance of payment deficits. Such internal di fficul ties may have partially led President Kaunda to seek to resolve the nagging Rhodesian issue. Ma1 awi . Since Ma1 awi an independence in 1964, President H. Kamuzu Banda has not nearly so consciously moved to terminate 1 inks with the white south. Despite appearances that lead critics to draw attention to newsworthy contacts, many of which (in diplomatic and strategic terms as well as in investments and financial aid) are undeniable and expanding,36 Malawi trade with the white south has shrunken since 1964 when twenty-two per cent of exports and forty- six per cent of imports were in that direction. By 1972 these figures had been reduced to 7.7 per cent and 34.4 per cent respectively. But South Africa's share rose from six per cent of exports and imports in 1964 to 5.5 per cent of exports and 29.5 per cent of imports in 1976. The supply of Malawian labor for South African mines has been cut back from a peak of around 130,000 miners per year. A 1974 Malawian order to suspend recrui tment had led to a drop to only 207 by 1977. That year recruitment was resumed and by early 1978 the num- ber of Malawians on the gold mines had risen to 20,000. It is not likely to go much higher. This South African pressure fulcrum has been eroded. One must not discount the deep involvement of Malawi with the white south. President Banda's panache at a time when the rest of black Africa sought to bury white rule in the region had an impact beyond mere trade and commercial contact. This data must be seen in its total context, that of a state that had not depended upon, but has chosen to link its economic future with South Africa. It is in the field of aid and investment that South Africa makes a greater impact. The secondment of South African governmental officials and private individuals to Malawi government offices, the financial assistance to build the new capital at Lilongwe and the Nacala rail 1 ink through Mozambique a increased bidding by South African firms on contracts in Malawi, and other projects supported by loans from the quasi -pub1 i c Industrial Development Corporation of South Africa etch the design of contact and mutual support deeper. In a way both the British and South Africans see it as a form of competition for influence in the country. Ironically, President Banda, who most vocally and consciously led the pro-"dialogue" with South Africa forces during the late 1960s and early 1970 s, has kept a low profile during the "detente" phase of regional affairs from 1974 to 1976. He has been consolidating his position domestically and seeking to normalize relations with his new neighbors (Frelirno) and his old ones. President Banda dealt openly and cordially with the Portuguese forces and had made major territorial claims on Tanzania and Zambia, among other less than friendly gestures. His earlier pragmatic opening southward has evol ved into an equally pragmatic re-association with black Africa. Botswana, Lesotho and Swaziland. The former High Commission Territories are reluctantly but integrally a part of South Africa's economic hinterland. A1 l are 1 and-locked, completely surrounded (except for a geometrical contact point between Botswana and Zambia in the middle of the Zambezi River and Swaziland's sixty miles of border with Mozambique) by whi te-governed territories. But being land-locked is not the sole cause of their economic vulnerability and their intimacy with South Africa. Early in their respective histories as separate protectorates, it was widely assumed in South Africa, in Great Britain and in the territories themselves that eventually they would be absorbed by South Africa. Thei r total econcmi c i~fras tructure and their financial , monetary and comnercial affairs were an appendage of South Africa. They participated in a common currency system, a commn tariff structure, common banking and commercial services and saw their communications and transport systems i nte- grated into those of South Africa. Botswana's economic 1 ifel ine, the rai lway, is still owned and operated by Rhodesian Railways, and its capital had been located at Mafeking in South African territory. All three territories export labor to South Africa (mostly for work on the mines). Lesotho is most pro- foundly affected; some 40-45 per cent of all adult Basuto males are employed in South Africa. For Swaziland and Botswana the figure is approximately fifteen per cent. This occurs with the full knowledge and cooperation of the respective governments. Wages, remittances and deferred pay are sent home by the employers ' organi zations and the workers. This, combi ned with recrui ti ng fees, taxes and revenue from customs and excise, all paid directly by the South African authorities to the "exporting" governments, render these govern- men ts dependent upon revenues generated in South Africa. While all three are, on paper, dependent on South Africa for their eco- nomic well-being, they do evidence varying degrees of vulnerabil i ty and varying perspectives on their independence. Lesotho is perhaps the most dependent and Swazi land the least. Leaders of each are aware of the circumstances and a1 1 pay 1 ip-service to the twin imperatives of living at peace with their neighbors and yet broadening thei r a1 ternatives (both economic and pol i tical ) . President Khama of Botswana has been most consistent since independence in his desire to maintain political independence in the face of economic isolation and con- straint. Swaziland, less critical of South Africa and less revolutionary in its determi nation to break South Africa's economic stranglehol d, has been relatively cordial in its dealings with and about South Africa. But Swaziland has an added dimension of vulnerability, and this refers to Mozambique. The monarchy of King Sobhuza has 1 i ttle in common with the radical Frel imo govern- ment that presently controls Swaziland's vital access to the sea. Simply because both are bl ack-governed shoul d not hide deep di fferences in purpose, social bases of support and governmental style. Lesotho, under Chief Jonathan Leabua, vascil lates between periods of intense collaboration with South Africa (1966-1972) and vocal hostility (1972 to date). In the cases of all three governments, however, the short-term options are few if the regime is to main- tain itself and the economy not revert to abject subsistence. There are various 1 imi ted or incremental a1 ternati ves (especial ly those pursued by Botswana) that prepare the peoples and their governments for a more independent econom- ic 1 ine and that lay the groundwork for future development, but in all instances choices are limited and risks are great. Tanzania. Depending on one's perspective, Tanzania and Zaire may or may not be included in Southern Africa. I happen to think they belong. In the case of Tanzania, a1 though historical and economic ties southward are margi nal , they seem to be growing. Tanzanian support for 1 iberation movements, parti- cularly Frelimo in Mozambique, led to continuous interaction with a hostile Portugal, with sympathetic inhabitants of Mozambique and now with a friendly government there. 37 The furtherance of Tanzanian efforts has a1 so contri - buted to greater coordination of her sanctuary role with Zambia. The 3il pipel ine between Dar es Salaam and the Zambian Copperbel t, new a1 1 -weather roads, and the Tan-Zam railway now 1 ink the two countries economically, as well as politically and strategically. So Tanzania, a1 though geographically not a part of Southern Africa and historically tied to East Africa, is coming to play a role in regional affairs. Diplomatic interaction regarding ini tia- tives to achieve a negotiated settlement in Rhodesia expand this role. Zaire. Zaire has long had economic ties southward. The Copperbel ts of Shaba (Katanga) and Zambia were intimately tied in infrastructural terms. Katanga's copper, moreover, was shipped out via the Benguela Railway and Lobi to, and her imports entered through that route. The capital city, Kinshasa, was in Bakongo country, and the continual flow of these peoples across the border (in both directions) linked Angola and Zaire. Today, with Zaire coveting the petroleum of Cabinda and Zaire's intimate involvement in the internal warfare in Angola (through its support of the FNLA) and vice versa, its impact on Southern African affai rs continues to be undeniable. Contemporary Events : Is the Region Becoming Ungl ued? There are two conflicting impulses vying for ascendency in regional affairs -- the impulse to atomism and the impulse to regional integration. Each is currently identi fied with important pol i tical forces. The atomists are largely those black pol i tical forces that seek independence in Namibia, and majority rule in the cases of Zimbabwe and South Africa. Included as well are leaders in a1 ready independent black states that wish to extricate thei r economies and policies from the pervasive tug of South African economic power. They have been atomists simply because to foster regional integration, given today's distribution of power and wealth, means to acquiesce in if not to contribute to South African dominance. In many ways these people are seeking to undo a pattern of interaction that has prevailed and been reinforced for decades and to resist the continued economic dynamism of the industrialized white South. We should not assume, however, that this attitude toward regional integration wi 11 always prevai 1 among the nationalist governments. The regional balance of forces is shifting, especially with Portugal 's departure. Selective inte- grati ve measures are proposed and implemented that invol ve independent black governments. The Zambian about-face on issues like Caborra Bassa and the Nacala rail link after the establishment of a Frelimo government illustrates a flexibility on the issue. On the other hand, given the eventual establish- ment of a majority government in South Africa, it would be likely that neigh- boring black states may still wish to avoid the centralizing and hegemonial tendencies associated with uneven development and economic asymmetry. A1 igned against these forces are the predominant economic interests in South Africa who view the outward movement as an opportunity to establish what they, and others before them, have regarded as a logical role for South Africa in the region, the industrial heartland of an increasingly cooperative and ultimately integrated economic entity characterized by continued rninori ty rule in South Africa itself .38 Proposals to institutional i ze these aspi rations, as a Southern African Common Market or Free Trade Area, are legion. Ironically, Afrikanerdom has itself been ambiguous about its role -- to lead the region and thereby solidify the ascendance of -- Vol k, or to withdraw behind the 1 aager and thereby guarantee the integrity of the culture. Engl ish-speaki ng South Africans have for long held the commercially-motivated viewpoint personi- fied in Cecil Rhodes, the empire builder, whose drive northward into his "hinter- land" has since marked the philosophy of those who came after him. It is in this ambiguous and dichotomous context that the pull and tug of regional af- fairs occurs. And as if such a kaleidoscope of pressures were not enough, extra-regional intrusi ve actors, anxious to see Southern Africa confarm to their own global image, provide added dimensions to the analysis. The collapse of the Salazar-Caetano regime in Portugal in April 1974, and i ts rep1 acement by a mi 1 i tary government of uncertai n ideological texture has done more to unsettle Southern African affairs than any single event since Rhodesian U.D. I. Indeed, in terms of the real i ty and profundity of the change it portends, UDI was merely a rear guard action, delaying trends set in motion with the British retreat from colonial empire. The military takeover, in contrast, led to the independence of two regional states dominated by revol u- tionary movements intent on redrawing the constellation of power in the region. So the mi li tary-strategic configuration of Southern Africa has shifted. Rhodesia and South Africa have lost an important ally. The "Front" has arrived at the Limpopo. Rhodesia's borders have been even more penetrable. And contrary to traditional patterns of interactions, this is just not another European event with a spillover into Africa. What is also important is that the Portu- guese government fell because its African wars became such a burden on its people, its economy and its military forces. Africa in this fashion kls had an impact on Europe quite different than most would have contemplated. Tho rise of black governments tempered in revol uti onary armed struggle provides a new ingredient in regional affai rs. Heretofore, African governments in the region ascended to power in relative tranquility. They were, to a large extent, the chosen agents of liberal colonial authorities anxious to designate succes- sor governments that would be willing to cooperate in the transition without too radically dismantl ing the colonial /neo-colonial structures. Both the Frelimo and MPLA governments are making revolutionary policies. Whether or not the exigencies of short-term economic stabi 1 i ty will tone down the revol utionary ardor and yield pragmatic policies is still open to question. Frelimo must pace itself carefully as it strives for self-reliance and economic indepen- dence. But it would also appear that the government is determined to achieve greater sel f-re1 iance soon. South African analysts who contend that real i srn will prevail and who thereby assume continued business as usual simply do not understand that it is just as realistic (a1 though over a far longer time perspective) for Mozambique to sever links until it can deal from a position of internal political and economic strength. There is at least as much evi- dence that the South African government and people have been sobered by the events of the past two years, and that South Africa has become more realistic and pragmatic when faced with the fait accompl i of Frel imo power in Maputo. In 1 ine with the sort of analysis developed earlier, it could be argued that Prime Minister Vorster sensed the fundamental instabil i ty of the Smith government in Rhodesia. Gi ven South Africa 's contemplated role as the dominant regional power, a determination had apparently been made that it would be futile and costly to try to prop up an inherently weak regime even though the racial and cultural affinities are evident. Hence, the reasoning in Pretoria probably runs 1 ike this. Let's try to serve as midwife for the birth of an African or racially mixed regime that would, at least, cooperate in the continued economic patterns and growth of the region. Ideally this new government would be led by bourgeois national i sts who, a1 though outwardly critical of South Africa and apartheid, would be wi 11 ing to maintain economic 1 inks and diplomatic ties with Pretoria, and who would not provide support for military actions against South Africa. Finding candidates for such a government, however, is almost as challenging as selling it to all important parties, i .e., white Rhodesians, black nationalists and peoples, and Zambia and other key black governments in the region and the OAU. Whether the Muzorewa-Sithole-Chirau combination is such a force is currently being argued. It may be that Vorster is banking on the basic proposition that the assumption of state and governmental responsi- bility by even less than ideal candidates will have a moderating effect on their performance in power. In other words, once in power, the black govern- ment will easily slip into old habits of pragmatism and reluctant cooperation and thereby become a status quo force, ideology and rhetoric notwithstanding. Such a government, it may be further felt, would be more difficult to displace than a white regime with a narrow internal base of power which draws the opprobrium of the world. In class terms, the new bourgeois regime, despite its nationalistic tendencies, can become accustomed to the perquisites of office and the blandishments of continued relations, and serve to deflect the ha1 f-hearted cri ticism of 1 i beral istic bourgeois governments el sewhere. Contributing to this reasoning is the fall-back realization that the Smith government would have eventually collapsed, and if it had done so in the crucible of revolutionary violence, a government comnitted to the total destruction of white power in the subcontinent would likely emerge. Such a government may yet prevail. But adaptable South African whites say, let's at least try to usher into power the right kind of government at a much more measured and manageable pac; than others may wish, and by so doing demonstrate our flexi- bil i ty and goodwi 11 in order to gain credit with neighboring black governments (who themsel ves are not noted for thei r radical ism), the general international cornunity and the new government we help to come to power. Such an "enlightened" incl ination to ride the waves of change, a1 bei t not the roughest surf on the beach, nonetheless shows an unusual courage for a South African ~overnrnent in foreign affairs. For the stakes, as South Africa sees it, are the very con- tinuation of white rule in South Africa. If they lose this game, there may be no rematch other than direct military conflict. Despite South Africa's professed comni tment to non-intervention in the affairs of neighboring states, South Africa began the difficult task of trying to open contacts with Zambia on the Rhodesian issue and thereafter to try to persuade Ian Smith to make concessions to Zimbabwe nationalists in order to bring the two parties to the negotiati ng table. 39 But white Rhodesia is exposed and untenable. The prospects of continued civil war in Zimbabwe are real as essentially two black nationalist groups again (as they did in the early 1960s) seek to assert their predominance. The problem, however, is that essential power in Zimbabwe is the issue, and it hardly looks negotiable to either national ist force. Si tuations, however, can change, depending on how long the internal settlement can remain glued. A1 though South Africa would appear to be showing some initiative and flexibility in its foreign pol icy, it must be remembered that South Africa's mi 1 i tary expenditures continue to grow, amounting to nineteen per cent of State expenditures and 5.1 per cent of the gross national product in 1977-78.40 The growth in absolute and relative terms is unmatched in the region and has led to virtual self-sufficiency in small arms and material. Evidence abounds that the South African government has not hesitated to use its military forces if they perceive that the protection of their interests demand it. Repeated incursions into Angola, the most spectacular in the Fall of 1975 and again in May 1978, have taken place. So the carrot is accompanied by the reality of the stick. And South Africa's domestic policies with regard to deal ing with those who reject and seek to alter the policy of separate development by any but the most ineffectual parliamentary means are no less repressive than in the days when South Africa did not seem to care to adjust to the realities of independence for colonial Africa. The feeling in Pretoria is that if South Africa can continue to grow economical- ly, and can relate to neighboring governments in such a fashion that they also become comnitted to economic growth at the expense of economic development and independence, and if South Africa can maintain a high level of domestic control, then South Africa can even weather the establishment of black governments on its borders. Portugal, or at least key segments of Portuguese and the military forces, could not withstand the pressure and opted out of southern Africa. White Rhodesia may just be learning to adapt, yet it comes at a time when adaptation may not be enough; revolution is demanded. South Africa's rulers contemplate stabilizing a tolerable regional order in a few years. A rnodus operandi , they contend, can be contoured. But forces beyond their control, notably African national ism and rev01 utionary social ism, are abroad in the region and for South Africans and others to seek to control them indirectly through hand picked or lesser of evil black candidates is a policy born of desperation. Steadily South Africa's a1 ternatives are being constricted. White South Africa's chosen path may be the only serious dynamic defense of the status quo open to them. It may deflect, delay, indeed even reverse temporarily the trends that seem so obvious today. But in the long run, as Coloured novel ist Richard Rive put it: "The end [of White dominance in South Africa] is in- evi table, but not predictable. " END NOTES The reader is urged to consult my book, Confrontation and Acconodation in Southern Africa: The Limits of Independence (Berkeley & Los Angeles: The University of California Press, 1973), for basic background data on international affairs in the region of Southern Africa. This section of the chapter is heavily dependent upon Johan Galtung, "A Structural Theory of Imperial ism," Journal of Peace Research 8 (1971 ) : 81-117. Sami r Amin argues, for instance, that "outward-oriented development" (integration into the worl d economy by concentration on production for export) "is not development but development of underdevelopment." Thus Gabon with a $600 per capita per year GDP "is not less but more under- developed" than Rwanda with $70, because the "structural chracteristics of underdevelopment" as described above are more marked in Gabon: ' De- velopment and Structural Change: The African Experience, 1950-1970," Journal of International Affai rs, 24 (1 970) : 21 7. See two works by Wi 11 iam Minter, Portuguese Africa and the West (New York and London: Monthly Review Press, 1972) and, Imperial Network and External Dependency: The Case of Angola, International Studies Series, Vol. 1 (Beverly Hills, California: Sage,1972). Bob Rowthorn, "Imperialism in the Seventies -- Unitv or Rivalry?" New Left Review, -no. 69 (September-October, 1971 ), pp. 31-54; two extensive editorials, "The End of U.S. Hegemony," Monthly Review 23 (October, 1971): 1-16; "Im~erialism in the Seventies: Problems and Pers~ectives," Monthly ~eview (March, 1972): 1-8; and Rick Wolff, "~e~emonic the - Contemporary World: Coopera ti on and Competition," paper prepared for the colloquium on "The Problem of Inequality in the Contemporary World-System," McGill University, Montreal, Canada, May 15-18, 1974. Ray Mauro Marini , "Brazil ian Subimperial ism," Monthly Review 23 (February, 1972): 14-24. Arghi ri Emmanuel , "Whi te-Settler Colonial ism and the Myth of Investment Imperialism," New Left Review, no. 73 (May-June 1972), pp. 36, 40 & 38. A general critique of Emmanuel's work, especially of his basic thesis that imperial ism is not solely a function of capital ism but of unequal exchange that presumably a1 1 industrial ized countries can indulge in, is Geoffrey Pi 11 i ng, " Imperi a1 ism, Trade, and ' Unequal Exchange ' : The work of Aghi ri [sic] Emnanuel," Economy and Society 2 (May, 1973): 164-185. See, Kenneth W. Grundy, "Anti-neo-colonial ism in South Africa's Foreign Pol icy Rhetoric," in Timothy M. Shaw and Kenneth A. Heard, eds., Coopera- tion and Conflict in Southern Africa: Papers on a Regional Subsystem (Washington, D.C. : University Press of America, 1976), pp. 351-364. For hi stori cal background and interpretation of the Angl o-Boer Wars, see : Eric A. Walker, A History of South Africa (London: Longmans, Green, 1957); Cornelis W. de Kiewiet, The Imperial Factor in South Africa (Cambridge: The University Press, 1937); and J. A. Hobson, The War in South Africa: Its Causes and Effects (~ew ~acmil -1900). Johan Galtung, "On the Effects of International Economic Sanctions: Wi th Exampl es from the Case of Rhodesia," Worl d Pol i tics 19 (Apri 1 1967) : 378-41 6. For example, the state-capitalist sector of the economy has grown immense- ly since 1948. It now covers all major segments of the infrastructure. Among other results, the state now accounts for some seventy-five per cent of steel output. It is involved in the manufacture of ammunition, weapons and war materiel, synthetic fuels and fertilizers, and other diverse products. For a history of this process, see: Earl Phillips, "State Requlation and Economic Initiative: The South African Case to 1960," ~nternational Journal of African Historical Studies 7 (1974) : 227-54. See Ruth First, Jonathan Steele and Christabel Gurney, The South African Connection: Western Investment in Apartheid (London: Temple Smith, 1972), pp. 147-92. Ibid., esp. pp. 9-80; and the press and Parliamentary flap triggered by the publication in The Guardian of a series of articles by Adam Raphael, beginning March 12, 1973, about the low wages paid by British firms to blacks employed in thei r South African subsidiaries. Charles Harvey, "The Effect of External Pressure on British Firms Investing in South Africa," in Shaw ii Heard, eds., Cooperation and Conflict, pp. 394-407. For example, Barbara Rogers argues that the balance of advantage in the economic 1 inks between Britain and South Africa lies "very much in South Africa's favour," South Africa's Stake in Britain (London: Africa Bureau, 1971 ). Foreign Minister Eric Louw in 1959 in "The Union and the Emergent States of Africa," in South African Bureau of Racial Affairs, South Africa in the African Continent (Stellenbosch: SABRA, 1959), p. 21. The idea of South Africa as a bridge can also be found in Fact Paper no. 5 (February, 1956), p. 12, and in Fact Paper no. 33 (April, 1957), p. 9 (both published by the South African Department of Information). See also Foreign Minister Hilgard Muller's later references to the same theme in, for example, Republic of South Africa, House of Assembly, Hansard, vol. 13 (1965), cols. 456-457. Editorial, "Imperialism in the Seventies," - Monthly Review 23 (March, 1972) : 1-8. For background on economi c re1 ati ons , see Grundy , Confrontation and Ac- commodation, Chap. 2. A radically updated version will appear as: Grundy, . . "Economic patterns in the New southern African Balance," in Gwendolen M. - Carter and Patrick O'Meara, eds., Southern Africa; The Continuing Crisis (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, forthcoming). An indispensible collection of materials is: John Dugard, ed., The South West Africa/Nami bia Dispute (Berkeley, Los Angeles & London: University of California Press, 1973). See also J.H.P. Serfontein, Namibia? (Rand- berg: Fokus Suid Pub1 ishers, 1976). Good descriptions of the guerrilla operations can be found in: Basil Davidson, ~oe and ~nthon~ Wil kinson, Southern Africa: The New Pol i tics of Rev01 ution (~armondsworth: Penguin, 1976) ; Kees Maxey, The Fiaht for Zimbabwe: The Armed Conflict in Southern Rhodesia Since UDI (London : Rex Col 1 i ngs, 1975) ; and Mi chael Raeburn, Bl ack Fi re! Accounts of the Guerrilla War in Rhodesia (London: Julian Friedmann. 1978). On the circumvention of sanctions, see Robert C. Good, U.D.I.: The Inter- national Pol i ti cs of the Rhodesian Rebel1 ion (Princeton. N. J. : Princeton University Press, 1973) ; Leonard T. Kapungu, he ~ni and ic Sanctions (~exington, Mass. : D.C. Heath & Co., 1973); and Harry Strack, Sancti ons : The Case of Rhodesi a (Syracuse : Syracuse Uni ve Press, 1978). Douglas G. Anglin, "Britain and the Use of Force in Rhodesia," in Michael G. Fry, ed., Freedom and Change: Essays in Honour of Lester B. Pearson (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 1975), pp. 43-75. For greater detail, see John Sprack, Rhodesia: South Africa's Sixth Province (London: International Defence and Aid Fund, 1974). "Why Zambia Wants to Talk," an interview with Vernon Mraanga, Financial Mai 1 (Johannesburg), 18 April 1975; my italics. The Star (Johannesburg), weekly air edition, 1 November 1975, p. 15. For a revealing expose of United States covert operations, see John Stockwell , In search of Enemies: A C. I .A. Story (New York: W.W. Norton, 1978). See also: Rene Lemarchand, "The CIA and U.S. Policy in Zaire and Angola," in Rene Lemarchand, ed., American Policy in Southern Africa: The Stakes and the Stance (Washington, D.C. : University Press of America, 1978), pp. 341-432. An official South African military account bears the revealing title, "How We Swept Cubans and MPLA Aside with Contemptuous Ease," Paratus (Pretoria), 28 (March, 1977). South Africa contends that tbei r forces were not repulsed, but withdrew only after initial encouragement and expected support from the United States had not materialized. In some measure this would confirm the Stockwell account of U.S. involvement. Financial Mai 1 (Johannesburg), 21 June 1974. Kei th Mi ddlemas , Caborra Bassa : Engi neeri ng and Pol i tics i n Southern Africa (London: Wei denfeld & Nicolson, 1975). The Constitution is reproduced in Facts and Reports (Amsterdam) 5 (4 October 1975): i tern 2230. See particularly Arts. 4, 14 and 22. The Star (Johannesburg), weekly ai r edi ti on, 28 June 1975, p. 1 . Ibid., 5 July 1975, p. 17. Financial Times (London), 12 May 1975; and Guardian (London), 14 May 1975. Guy Arnold, "Changing the Communications Map," Africa Report 20 (July/ August, 1975) : 37-41 . The inadequacies of the harbor at Dar es Salaam are discussed in: B. S. Hoyle, "African Politics and Port Expansion at Dar es Salaam," The Geographical Review 68 (January, 1978): 31-50. The Rhodesi a-Zambi a Border Closure: January-February 1973 (London : Inter- national Defence and Aid Fund, May 1973). Douglas G. Angl in, "Zambian Disengagement from Southern Africa and Inte- gration with East Africa, 1964-1972: A Transaction Analysis ," in Shaw & Heard, eds., Cooperation and Conflict, pp. 228-289. Carolyn McMaster, Malawi : Foreign Pol icy and Development (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1974). See, ~enneth W. Grundy, "Host Countries and the Southern African Liberation Struggle," Africa Quarterly 10 (Apri 1-June, 1970) : 15-24. For example, "Southern Africa Trade Bloc?", The Star, weekly air edition, 11 October 1975, p. 15. Dougles G. Angl in, "Zambia and Southern African 'Detente ' ," International Journal 30 (Summer, 1975) : 494ff. Republic of South Africa. Department of Defence, White Paper on Defence, 1977 (Sirnonstown: The SA Navy, 1977), p. 14. 126 THE QUEST FOR EAST AFRICAN UNITY: 'ONE STEP FORWARD, TKO STEPS BACKNARD' J. Gus Liebenow, Indiana University In April, 1977 the Tanzanian Minister for Home Affairs announced that the 450 mile border separating Tanzania from Kenya would be "permanently sealed". This action was the culmination of a long series of disputes between the two states over transport, trade, taxes, tourism and a range of pol i tical issues. Concurrently with this action relations between Uganda and its two East African neighbors had reached a new low in the continuing crisis which has raged since Idi Amin seized power in 1971. The significance of these events has had ramifications far beyond the three states dire~tly invol ved. For indeed, they constituted devastating, if not fatal, blows to the continent's rnos t dramatic case of regional integration. Throughout history attempts to create pol i tical comnuni ty at an increasingly larger scale have been recurrent phenomena. Wi thin the present generation people on each of the major continents have witnessed efforts to expand the limits of political community. In many instances these goals have been pursued by those whose primary motivation has been the domination of one's neighbors -- as in the cases of Germany and Japan during the second quarter of this century. Attempts to enlarge the scope of political communi ty, however, are a1 so being pursued today in Western Europe, Central America, Southeast Asia and parts of Africa by those with goals that are less subject to challenge. These goals woul d i ncl ude mutual defense, the maxirni zing of econorni c opportunities within a region for the benefit of all parties, or the creation of a political system which sublimates or balances potentially hostile differences of a linguistic, re1 i gious, racial or cul tural nature. In many respects Africa is an excellent 1 aboratory for the study of peaceful efforts to expand the notion of political comrnuni ty beyond the limits of the existing nation-states. By an informal count, over two dozen plans for some form of integration involving two or more African states have been advanced in the past two decades. Indeed, under the banner of Pan-Africanism, the commitment to cooperation or consol idation above the state level has become an article of pol i tical faith among the overwhelming majori ty of Africa's leadership in the post-colonial era. In its least politically operational version, Pan-Africanism merely assumes the psychological, racial, cultural or spiritual identity of all the people of the continent as well as their dispersed off-spring in the New World. It is an identity based upon their snared experience as victims of the slave-trade and European colonial rule. Increasingly, however, acceptance of Pan-Africanism as an ideology imp1 ici assumes the need for administrative or political structures through which citizens of the African states can achieve tangible benefits from economic, cultural and pol i tical cooperation. The variety of structures created or proposed in Africa can be instructive for other areas of globe. In terms of numbers of geographic units involved the African evidence covers a broad spectrum. At one extreme is the bilateral posture as exemplified in the Mano River Customs Union between Liberia and Sierra Leone or in the collaborative efforts of Tanzania and Zambia to construct and operate a railway line from the copperbelt to Dar es Salaam. Multilateral cooperation on a regional basis is evidenced in the East African Comnon Services Organization, the economic cooperation among fifteen states of West Africa, and in UDEAC -- the cooperative effort of several former French dependencies in Central Africa. At the far end of the spectrum is the continental approach, which was so ardently espoused by the late Kwame Nkrumah of Ghana and which has seen 1 imi ted fruition in the creation of the Organization of African Unity. The qua1 i ty of approaches attempted in Africa within the bilateral, regional and continental frameworks also gives the African experience uni versa1 significance. The pol i tical model, emulating the experience of the thirteen American states in 1887-89, has had mixed reception. Indeed, Nkrumah, who advocated not only continental unity but the imperative of the political approach as well, frequently referred to the American example in his proposal for a United States of Africa. This model assumes the necessity of creating system-wide political institutions as a requisite in achieving coordination of economic, cultural and other affairs among previously independent or autonomous enti ties. As in the American experience, the participating units would have to surrender or agree to share their previous monopoly over the use of domestic and external force, over taxation, over direct contacts with the individual citizen and over relationships among the states and wi th external powers. The politic31 model nas been largely rejected at the continental level, with the OAU being largely a consultative body rather than a political collectivity. Similarly, political integration at the regional level has remained a hope rather than a reality. Kwame Nkrumah's various plans for the political union of Ghana with, inter -- ia, Guinea, Ma1 i and even Liberia, never advanced beyond the blue- 125 print stage. Furthermore, the heroic gesture of Julius Nyerere -- in suggesting a delay in Tanganyikan independence so that it could be coordinated with the simultaneous independence of Kenya and Uganda within the framework of a politically unified East African state -- also failed to reach fruition. The only other efforts at regional pol i ti cal integration took place under the aegis of European imperial ism: the union of the four provinces of South Africa in 1910 and the short-lived Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland, which was dissolved as Zambia and Malawi achieved indepen- dence as separate entities. It has only been at the bilateral level that political consolidation has manage to a1 ter the b,oundaries established by the European colonial powers at the end of the nineteenth and beginning of the twentieth centuries. In most of the cases of bilateral consolidation the idea was launched, if not consummated, prior to one or both of the parties attaining independence. This is particularly true ~f the former United Nations Trust Territories, with British Togoland being absorbed by GLana, Ital ian-administered Soma1 ia being united with British Soma1 i land at independence and the northern and southern sectors of British Cameroon opting respectively for union with Nigeria and the former French Cameroon as independence approached. Three other examples of pre-independence pol i tical union have witnessed, or are now experiencing, disaster. The Ma1 i Federation, for example, which had united the forme French territories of Senegal and the Soudan, lasted only two months beyond indepen- dence. The decision of the Four Powers at the end of the Second World War to integrate Italian Eritrea into the Ethiopian Empire is now being effectively chal lenged by various Eritrean 1 iberation groups. Similarly, the division of the Spanish Sahara between Morocco and Mauretania is a1 so being contested by "1 i beration" 1 groups supported by A1 geria. The only example of post-independence political inte- gration has been the 1964 union of Zanzibar and Tanganyika. It was only 1977, that the Tanzania experiment began to have substantially more than symbolic value. It is true that both units had recognized Julius Nyerere as President and that Zan- zibar, however, continued to control its own domestic and military matters and even conducted i ts foreign relations outside the framework of the Tanzanian Ministry of Foreign Affairs. There was also, until 1977, the anomaly of two parties -- one for the mainland and the other for Zanzibar -- existing within a single party state! The converse of the pol i tical model is the functional approach to transnational integration. Essentially, it has been this model that has been followed in Western Europe today and is currently being pursued by the leaders of fifteen West African states as well as by the leaders of several former French territories in Africa where transnational cooperation is being sought in fiscal matters, transportation, customs duties, research and other "non-poli tical" fields. Advocates of the functional approach to integration argue that pol i tical unity -- whether explicitly or implicitly recognized as an end qoal of cooperation -- can only be accomplished on the basis of a prior demonstration of the feasi- bili ty and the value of cooperation in non-poli tical matters. The surrender of state sovereignty is such an emotional issue that the participants must be convinced that the gains will offset the losses. Interstate cooperation per se, - however, does not inevitably lead to political integration. If the latter is the implied goal, cooperation must cover a complex of non-political issues. Secondly, the quality of cooperation is a factor. The areas singled out must be regarded by the parties as critical to the functioning of their respective societies. They must be of such a character that once the benefits of cooperation begin to be realized it would be difficult for any of the parties to advocate a return to the previously autonomous situation. Hence, this was the strategy of the West Europeans in ini tiatins integrative efforts in the areas of coal and steel production. Thirdly, the process of integration leading to pol i tical unity must remain a dynamic one. Accompl ishments in a series of endeavours must lead to demands for cooperation in other areas in order to sustain the drive to political unity. To paraphrase the historian Seeley, political unity would be achieved thereby, in "almost a fit of absence of mind." It is against this background that we undertake an analysis of the problems of functional integration on a regional basis in East Africa. The three states directly involved -- Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda -- have a combined population of 36 mill ion inhabitants and cover an area somewhat larger than that of the nine states included in the European Economic Comnuni ty. Unl i ke the West European situation, however, the economies of the East African states are based largely upon agri cul ture and mineral extraction, with some beginnings of industrial ization in Kenya. Curiously, however, the introduction of functional integration in East Afri ca i n 1948 antedates the launchi ng of serious efforts towards European economic integration by three years. The Origins of East African Dreams of Unity Like many of the schemes for functional cooperation which have emerged in Africa during the independence era, cooperation in East Africa has largely taken place within a framework laid down during the colonial period and was^ in fact the inspiration of the former colonial cfficial s. Proposals for the pol i tical integration of Britain's territorie, in East Africa began to be floated as early as the First World War. Indeed, the German expulsion from Tanganyika made possible the realization of Cecil Rhodes' dream of a great red swath on the map from the Cape to Cairo. Although belatedly the most persistent advocates of this idea during the colonial period were tne Kenya white settlers, initially it was British officials in London and colonial administrators on the local scene who advanced and sustained the concept. At several stages, moreover, the unification of East Africa was viewed as part of a greater scheme to unite all British territories between the Sudan and the Zambezi River. This would have provided Nyasalahd (now Malawi ) and Northern Rhodesia (now Zambia) with direct access to the Indian Ocean and lessened the dependence of these two territories on the whi te-dominated regimes in South Africa and Southern ~h0desia.l Sir Harry Johnston, a longtime colonial officer who had been responsible for the extension of British rule in both Nyasaland and Uganda, saw this grand scheme of East and Central African closer union as a device for el iminati ng "balkanization" -- the popular European political scapegoat as the cause of war in the post-World War I era? An even more persistent advocate in official circles, however, was Mr. L.S. Amery, a staff officer who ultimately assumed the post of British Colonial Secretary in the mid-1920s. Even before the British forces under General Jan Smuts had defeated the Germans in Tanganyika, Amery had allied himself with Smuts in pressing for the inclusion of Tanganyika in a federation of British dependencies. Amery felt not only that the larger territory would be easier to administer but that it would more efficiently contribute to the needs of the empire.3 He was supported in this position by a member of the Economic Commission of the East Africa Protectorate in 1919 who argued that strategically, financially and ideological ly (that is, the superiority of the British presence in Africa) closer union of East and Central Africa was a necessi ty.4 It was not unti 1 1924, in response to a British House of Commons resolution, that any official action was taken on the idea of closer union. A comnission under the chairmanship of W. Orrnsby-Gore was dispatched to East Africa to investigate economic conditions and development plans and to recommend policies for the coordi- nation of transport, agriculture and medicine in the several territories. To the chagrin of Amery, who had become Colonial Secretary upon the fall of the Labour government in 1924, the Ormsby-Gore Commission did not recommend closer union. The commission instead argued that the exDense and di ffi cul ties of comrnuni cation made such a move impractical .5 Undaunted, Amery persisted in his goal by having his nominee for the governorship of Kenya, Sir Edward Grigg, champion the idea. Subsequently another commission, under the chai rmanship of Si r Hi 1 ton Young, was appointed to investigate closer union, and still a further inquiry into the idea was conducted in 1929 by the Permanent Under-Secretary of State, Sir Samuel Itlilson.6 Ul timately the series of recommendations were submitted to a Joint Select Committee of both Houses of Par1 iament. The comni ttee's recommendation was that closer union of a political or constitutional character, while in many respects desirable, was inapproapriate at that time. The best that could be hoped for was greater cooperation and coordination through periodic rneeti ngs of the governors of the three territories -7 This recommendation was accepted by the British government in 1931, and there the matter of political union rested. During the decade of pressure from Amery and others at the official level, it was apparent that the idea of closer political union had few advocates among the permanent residents of East Africa. The Africans in general were a poorly organized pol i tical force at that time. Individual Africans, nevertheless, did give testimony in opposition to the idea, arguing that the first consequence of closer union would be further alienation of land in Uganda and Tanganyika to Europeans along the 1 ines followed in Kenya. The most vociferous organized African opposition came from the Baganda. This largest of the twenty ethnic groups in Uganda suspected that their privileged position as an 'agreement state' within the Uganda Protectorate woul d be jeopardized through their participation in any federal legislative arrangement which would find them enjoying minority status. Similarly, the Asians in the three territories for the most part opposed closer union, unless they could be accorded equality of representation with the dorni nan t European group. For differing reasons, the Europeans in the three territories were not initially enthusiastic about federation. The Kenya settlers feared that it would compl icate their plans to make Kenya a European-managed self-governing colony. The Europeans in Uganda, already chaffing over customs charges and the cost of operating the railroad which inexorably linked landlocked Uganda to Kenya's seaport at Mornbasa, feared further domination by the comercia1 interests in iiai robi ; Tanganyi ka settlers were equal ly suspicious of their neighbors in Kenya, particularly after it was proposed that the agricul turally-rich area around Moshi and Arusha in northern Tanganyi ka s houl d be ceded to Kenya. In the end, one of the most effective opponents of the idea was not a resident of the region, but Sir Dona1 d Cameron, who had become Governor of Tanganyika in 1925.~ Cameron viewed closer union as a real threat to the economic development of one of Britain's poorest dependencies. He based his fear of Kenya settlers not only on their coveting of the Arusha-Moshi area, but also upon thei r opposition to the construction of the Mwanza-Tabora railway link, which would divert some traffic away from Lake Victoria and the Kenya- Uganda Railway. His greatest concern, however, was that closer union would undermine his implementation of ' indirect rule, ' a philosophy of colonial administration of which he had become enamored while serving under Lord Lugard in Nigeria. He feared that the Kenya practice of appointing warrant chiefs would be appl ied throughout the region under closer association. In any event the British government in the decade following the rejectic~ of closer union by Parliament gave a very low priority to reopening the question. The government was much more concerned wi th battl i ng the worl dwi de depression and coping with the growing pol i tical and military crisis in Europe. Concurrently, however, the previously hostile Kenya settlers under Lord Del amere began to view closer union with enthusiasm. Sensing that eventually the ideas of Amery just might prevail, Lord Delamere decided to strengthen the bargaining position of the Kenya settlers. He began insisting that Nairobi would have to be the capital of any future East African federation and that the whites in Kenya would have to have an elected rnajori ty in that colony's legislative counci 1.9 Del arnere managed, moreover, to convene two conferences of white settlers from several East and Central African territories in 1925 and 1926 in order to galvanize the Europeans into presenting a united front in dealing with any proposals for political reorganization. What ul tirnately did propel the Europeans in Kenya and Tanqanyi ka into a more positive posture with respect to closer union was the spectre of Tanganyi ka being sacri ficed to Nazi Germany's demands for colonial lebensraum. The indecisiveness on the part of both the Bal dwin and the Chamberlain governments in the 1930s convinced the settlers that their fears were well-grounded. A series of peti tions were made to the Bri tish government demanding closer union as an assurance that Tanganyika's place in the British Empire would be assured.10 The petitions were apparently ignored, but Tanganyi ka remained under Bri tish control During the Second World War the idea of closer union was again bruited about in various forms. One proposal emanating from Kenya was that a Joint East African War Council be established to provide for common policy under a unified comnand. Both administrators and residents in Uganda and Tanganyi ka rejected the idea. Also rejected was the revival of one of Awry's pet projects, the naming of the Governor of Kenya as the High Comnissioner for all British areas between the Sudan and the Zambezi. The only regional proposal that did bear fruit was the es tab1 ishment of a Joint Economic Counci 1 to coordinate economic and comercial planning for six territories in East and Central Africa (including Zanzibar, but excluding Southern Rhodesia). Created in 1940, the Council did not survive the war, and it was constantly criticized for favoring Kenya's economic development and welfare at the expense of its neighbors. l1 Creation of the East Rfrica High Comission Of greater significance than the wartime cooperation were the statements made in London towards the end of the Second World War which indicated that the British coalition government of Conservatives and Labourites was thinking in terms of amalgamation -- either administratively or politically -- of colonial units. The purpose of amalgamation would be to carry out the provisions of the Colonial Development and Welfare Act of 1940 in a more effective fashion and to rationalize defense planning within the British Empire. With respect to East Africa the British government insisted that it was only advocating economic and technical cooperation rather than political union. The statements, nevertheless, were viewed with suspicion by members of all races. l2 First of all, the post-war proposals regarding the creation of an East Africa High Comission seemed to give a pre-eminent role to Kenya by virtue of the Governor of Kenya being chairman of the Commission, with the other two governors as his colleagues. Secondly, the creation of an executive authority and a Central Legislative Assembly were regarded as the thin edge of a wedge in creating political institutions. Fears were not allayed by the claim that the High Commission had only 1 imi ted authority with respect to specified economic and technical functions and was expressly denied authority to deal with basic administration, pol ice services, education, agriculture, forestry, veterinary services, health, labor and other matters which would be left to the terri- torial governments. Thirdly, the various formulae regarding racial represen- tation in the Assembly seemed to displease everyone except the Indians. Despi te the many expressed ~nisgivings, the proposal was pushed through by the British government, and the East Africa High Commission came into existence on January 1, 1948.13 The final grounds for suspicion of the High Commission was that pari passu with events in East Africa the British Labour government was initiating the proposals for the political amalgamation of the two Rhodesias and Nyasaland. This was taking place without substantial consul tation with the African majorities in any of the territories. It was against this background that the 'Kabaka Crisis' of 1953 in Uganda must be evaluated. The event which triggered the political turmoil in Buganda was a remark of the Colonial Secretary in London on June 30, 1953, in which he praised the Central African Federation and suggested that the idea might well be extended to East Africa. There was immediate fear in Buganda that federation would threaten the pri vi leged position of the Baganda within East Africa and subordinate their intererts to those of the Kenya white settlers. Accordingly, a broad spectrum of politiral groups in Buganda compelled Kabaka Mutesa to take a firm stand not only against federation but also against submerging of Buganda's distinct political identity within a unified Uganda. In a heated reaction to the situation Governor Sir Andrew Cohen took the extraordinary step of deporting the Kaba ka, thereby pl unging Buganda into pol i tical chaos. A1 though much more was involved in the 1955 settlement which ultimately brought the Kabaka back to Buganda, it was clear that closer political union under the colonial umbrella had been dealt a deathblow by the intransigence of the Baganda -- at least insofar as European settler or British Colonial Office initiative was concerned.14 There was, however, one further attempt made at political union in East Africa under the aegis of the colonial umbrella. The inspiration, however, was African in origin. This was the offer of Julius Nyerere in 1961 to delay the scheduled independence for Tanganyi ka if there could be immediate progress on plans for the political federation of East Africa, with Africans in control of the process. This was an attempt to give concrete action to the words he had prophetical ly uttered the year previously, indicating that the feeling of unity which now exists could be whittled away if each country gets its independence separately and becomes too open to the temptations of nationhood and the intrigues of those who find their strength in the weakness of small nations . . . . Further the leaders of each state will become so preoccupied with the problems of their own government that the long-term advantages which can come from the ectabl ishment of a federation wi 11 get crowded out of considerat ;on.l5 Unfortunately, the British Colonial Office failed to respond positively to Nyerere's remarkable offer, and the African leadership in both Kenya and Uganda was unable to respond due to the great domestic political problems that each of them faced. Independence, thus, came to each country without the assumed benefits of pol i tical federation. Economic and Technical Cooperation under Col oni a1 Rule Despi te di ffi cul ties encountered on the pol i tical front, the economic and technical integration of East Africa under colonial rule had rapidly proceeded. The economic interdependence of two of the territories, Kenya and Uganda, had in a sense been forged much earlier when the British decided in the nineteenth century to add Buganda and the other Uganda kingdoms to the British holdings in Kenya, and, secondly, when the decision was made to construct the rai lway 1 inking Uganda to the Kenya port of Mombasa. During the first two decades of the twentieth century, however, the links served as an irritant to elements in Uganda rather than an unmitigated blessing. Indeed, the designation of the customs union in 1917, permitting the free flow of domestic comrnodi ties between Kenya and Uganda and standardizing customs col lections for the two countries, at first only further aggravated the situation. The Uganda commercial interests chafed under what they regarded as the unfair division of the customs receipts and of the railway charges and revenues. Some lessening of the hostility occurred in the early 1920s when a new formula was devised for distributing customs receipts and Uganda was included on the membership of the newly created Railway Council, which supervised the operation of the Mombasa- Kampala 1 ine. A similar history of suspicions arose in Tanganyi ka after the First World War, particularly when plans were developed to have the produce of the Moshi-Arusha area routed through the Kenya port of Kilindini rather than through Tanga or Dar es Salaam. It was not until 1927 that the free trade aspects of the common market were extended to Tanganyika, and the common customs administration only took effect in Tanganyika in 1949, after the creation of the High Commission. Para1 lel with the proposals for closer political union during the 1920s and 1930s, a series of recommendations were made for the extension of coopera- tion in economic and technical matters. For example, the Grigg scheme of 1927 -- ultimately rejected by the British cabinet -- envisioned a federal counci 1 for East Africa entrusted with control of transportation, customs, defense, communications and research throughout the region. l6 Perhaps due to the League of Nations Mandate status of Tanganyika, which gave it special international significance, most of the constructive economic cooperation among the three territories during the inter-war period was brought about informal ly and wi thout specific legal authorization from the British government. Obviously, the Colonial Office in London was aware of these developments. I refer to the schemes for cooperation and coordination which emerged from the annual meetings of the East African governors which took place during the 1930s. These conferences produced agreements -- or agreements in principle -- regarding uni form taxation pol icy with respect to Africans, elementary education in the vernacular, transport and communica- tions, and industrialization. One very concrete move -- objected to by the German member of the League of Nations Permanent Mandates Commission -- was the 1932 amalgamation of the East African postal services. The decisions of the Governors ' Conferences, however, were not always subjected either to public discussion or to the consent of the territorial legislative councils. In many instances the agreements could have been unconstitutional. At the end of the war the Labour government, in the name of greater efficiency, was commi tted to some form of i nter-terri torial cooperation. Recognizing the fears in East Africa regarding closer political union, the East Africa High Commission was advanced as a mechanism for furthering economic and technical cooperation. The organization which came into effect in 7948 pro- vided for a series of new or reorganized agencies that would provide comnon services throughout the three territories. The areas speci fi cal ly covered were posts and tel ecommuni cati ons ; rai 1 roads, harbors, and inland steamers ; touri srn; East African Airways; scientific research in a broad range of fields; joint customs and tax systems; shared currency; comnon immigration controls; an integrated university system; and the framework for a comnon economic market. These agencies were in addition to the other supra-terri torial insti tutions of cooperation such as the East African Navy and the East African High Court of Appeals. Despite the initial misgivings of the African political leaders in Uganda and Tanganyi ka regardi ng the East Africa Hi gh Comni ssion, the technical services were handled in an even-handed fashion and did contribute to the development of the region as a whole. Kenya, it is true, enjoyed a favored position as the most prosperous of the three territories and had the headquarters of the High Commission establ ished in Nairobi . The Colonial Office, nevertheless, managed to supervise the operations of the High Comnission and resolve points of conflict among the three governors. Indeed, the system worked so we1 1 that Julius Nyerere and TANU were resolved that -- in the absence of federation prior to independence -- the cooperati ve arrangements with Kenya and Uganda shoul d pers i st after Tanganyi ka recei ved i ts i ndependence i n December 1961. Accordingly, the High Commission was transformed into the East African Common Services Organi zation. The High Authority for the Organization consisted of the heads of government of the three units involved. Gone, however, would be the staying power of an external body, such as the Colonial Office, to resolve controversy. Each state could exercise a veto with respect to policies it regarded as prejudicial to its best interests .l The Framework of Coo~eration in the Post-Inde~endence Period The failure of the Ugandan and Kenyan nationalist leaders to respond to Nyerere's offer regarding federation prior to independence did not indicate hostil i ty towards the idea of pol i tical union. It was apparently attributable to the matter of timing and the serious internal problems both Jomo Kenyatta in Kenya and Mi 1 ton Obote in Uganda faced. Indeed, once the Baganda crisis in Uganda had been resol ved and Uganda achieved independence as a federal state, the call for federation was again made. A1 though this may have been timed to force the British to set an early date for Kenyan independence, the three leaders did make a public announcement in June 1963 of their intentions to achieve federation of the three East African states by the end of that year.18 Federation did not in fact take place by the end of 1963. Kenya did achieve its independence wi th i ts 1 eaders openly comni tted to the concept of pol i ti cal unity. A conference held in 1964 at Kampala, however, clearly brought out the economic considerations which were to compl icate the pol i tical question for the ensuing decades. Indeed, the situation had so a1 tered that the original champion of coopera ti on, Tanganyi ka, threatened wi thdrawal from even the i nformal common market arrangements a1 ready in existence. It was apparent that it was no longer sufficient to argue that increased complementarity among the three partners woul d ultimately be of benefit to all. Efficiency could not be the sole criterion in making decisions regarding the location of new industrial and other forms of development opportunities in the region. For there was a genuine insistence on the part of the two less developed participants -- Tanganyika and Uganda -- that the benefits of devel opment be distributed more quickly and more widely through- out the region. Otherwise employment opportunities, revenues from trade and the generation of weal th through industrial ization would accrue to the more privileged Kenyan economy, to the neglect of Tanganyika and Uganda. As matters stood in 1964, Kenya -- and Nairobi in particular -- enjoyed distinct economic advantages over the rest of East Africa. The rationale for this economic advantage is complex. Partially it is a matter of geography. Kenya serves as the transit route not only for landlocked Uganda but also for the most prosperous region of Tanzania, the area around Moshi and Arusha. The harbor at Mombasa is superior to anything along the Tanzanian coast. Given Kenya's varying a1 ti tudes and cl imatic conditions, moreover, its agricultural products are more diversified than those of its neighbors. During most of the twentieth century, it has had a well educated and relatively prosperous European population that i ntroduced many techno1 ogical innovations in agri cul- ture as well as commencing industrial development. Being a Crown Colony, more- over, external investors felt far more secure in putting their funds into Kenyan development rather than risking them on the Uganda protectorate or the Tanganyi ka Mandate (1 ater Trust) Territory. Over time, Uganda and Tanganyi ka had become the consumers of Kenya's manufactured goods which were protected by the common market's tariff wall. Trade relations were not reciprocal, for the cotton, sisal, coffee, tea and other bulk commodities of Uganda and Tanganyika were sold abroad rather than in Kenya. Finally, Nairobi enjoyed distinct advantages wi th respect to the concentration of manpower ski 11 s , banking and other conercial faci 1 i ties, transportation, electrical and other power needed for industrial ization, and other factors. Thus both foreign and domestic East African investors found the situation compel1 ing to opt for Kenya in the expan- sion of existing -- or the location of new -- industrial and comnercial enter- pri ses. The Kampala Agreement of 1964 attempted to correct the imbalances between Kenya and its two neighbors by resort to several devices :I9 (1 ) compel1 ing beer, footwear, cement and other firms operating in all three countries to increase production in the deficit countries as a way of reducing imports from Kenya; (2) providing the defict countries with monopolies in new industries, such as fertilizers in Uganda and tires and tubes in Tanzania; (3) bolstering production of a commodity produced in more than one state by allowing the deficit state or states to apply quotas on imports from the surplus country or countries; (4) increasing sales general ly from deficit to surpl us states; and (5) reaching an early agreement within the East African commn market on more equitable distribution of industrial development by wa;, both of positive induce- ments as well as arbitrary allocations of new industries to certain states. The Kampala Agreement obviously favored Tanganyika and Uganda and perhaps accounts for the failure of Kenya to ratify it. Nevertheless, despite the lack of formal acceptance, the first provision was carried out through pressure being exerted on local firms with headquarters in Kenya. The quota provision, moreover, was all too liberally implemented by Tanzania with respect to an expanding 1 ist of i tems imported from Kenya. Curiously, a1 though it did reduce the trade deficit between Tanzania and Kenya, Tanzania was compel led to import the needed items from abroad, frequently at even higher prices. This action neither helped Tanzania 's overall balance of payments problems nor encouraged complementari ty within East Africa. The a1 location of new industries to deficit countries, moreover was not entirely a sacrifice on Kenya's part since these firms had not yet decided to locate within East Africa. The informal ad hoc implementation of the "disengagement" features of the Kampala Agreement was fol lowed by other actions which threatened the tenuous progress a1 ready made within the East African common market. The first was the break-up of the East African Currency Board by virtue of Tanzania's decision in 1965 to issue its own currency. This was followed two years later by the nationalization of banking and other monetary institutions and the announcement of the Arusha Declaration. The latter provided Tanzania with a distinct political-economic ideology which effectively set Tanzania on a separate path of development from that followed by its neighbors. These developments came on the heels of even earlier actions which eliminated supra- national institutions. Tanganyi ka, for example, had opted out of the East Afri can Navy shortly after independence. Uganda, upon achievi ng i ts independence, withdrew from the East African tourist board on the grounds that it paid 25 per cent of the costs of the agency but received only nine per cent of the tourist revenues wi thin East Afri ca. Real izing these actions were eroding the comnuni ty, the three leaders returned to Kampala in June 1967 to consider steps for strensthening the cornon market and for the first time giving a legal and comprehensive basis to the many steps that had been taken since the 1917 customs union between Kenya and Uganda had been introduced. The 1967 Treaty for East African Coopera- tion stressed the need not only for economic growth of the region, but for the "accelerated, harmonious and balanced development" of East Africa. While retaining the common customs tariff for East Africa and striving for the long- term objective of free trade within the region, the Treaty did provide for short- term quanti tati ve l imi ts being imposed on industrial products (as we1 1 as exemption of agricultural products) in order to protect infant industries. For a period up to fifteen years, transfer taxes -- a euphemism for tariffs -- could be levied against Kenya products to encourage industrial development in the deficit states. A1 though restrictions were imposed on the use of transfer taxes, this has constituted the most serious inroad on the concept of East African free trade. Three additional provisions of the Treaty were the fiscal incentives to new industries; the establishment of an East Afric:,n Development Bank, designed parti cularly to assist Tanzania and Uganda ; and the provision for extending the East African Comuni ty to other nations in Africa, such as Zambia, Zaire, Mozambique and Ethiopia. The new Community perpetuated most of the state sovereignty features of the Common Services Organization, for each of the heads of state, who collec- tively constitute the East African Authority, can exercise a veto. But there was an attempt to create a bureaucracy with a commitment to the region as a whole. A further effort to equal ize the involvement of the three participating states was the decision to locate the headquarters of two major operations within each of the states involved. Thus the Comuni ty headquarters was located at Arusha, the Harbors Corporation in Dar es Salaam, the Bank and also Posts and Telecommuni- cations were to go to Kampala and Railways and the Airways Corporations would remain in Nairobi. Assessment of Coo~eration in the Pos t-Inde~endence Era In the fourteen to sixteen years of independence and the decade since the 1967 Treaty er tab1 ishing the East African Communi ty, the progress of functional integration has been -- to paraphrase Lenin -- "one step forward; two steps backward". There is still a vigorous verbal comnitment on the part of Presidents Nyerere, Kenyatta and Amin to the vital necessity of East African cooperation. Yet, instead of economic and technical cooperation drawing the members of the Comnunity closer together politically, the states have barely been able to main- tain diplomatic relations with each other. Most accerbated have been the relations between Tanzania and Uganda, which since 1971 have been in a virtual state of war. This situation stemmed initially from the political and military support which Nyerere attempted to provide Mi 1 ton Obote following his ouster by General Idi Amin. The conflict has been a constant source of friction, with recurrent raids across the Uganda-Tanzania border and the massing of troops having brought most interstate trade and other forms of contact to a standstill. Similarly, relations between Uganda and Kenya have flared-up from time to time over issues such as the trans-shipment of Russian tank ferries to Uganda over Kenya roads, the rash "historic claims" of Idi Amin to large areas of western Kenya in 1975, and the support given by Kenya to the Israeli comnandos follow- ing their 1976 raid on Entebbe airport. Such conflict has led to the temporary closing of borders or demands by Kenya that Uganda pay for oil and other essential goods in foreign currency and pay in advance of the actual sale. To complete the circle, the "permanent sealing" of the Kenya-Tanzania border in 1977 was but the culmination of a series of border closings, mutual deporta- tions of each others' citizens and fiscal harrassment which has plagued relations between Kenya and Tanzania. The absence of a heal thy set of diplo- matic relations among the leaders of the three states, however, is not the only problem which has checkered the path to integration. Ideological Postures. In part the diplomatic and military confrontations have been attributable to the divergences in ideology which have developed in the period si nce independence. Admi ttedly difficulties can and do arise even among leadership groups with similar ideological view points when each is attempting to consoli- date its position within a relatively unstable political milieu. When the divergences are as great as they are in East Africa today, however, the possi- bility of discord becomes more of a certainty. In many respects Tanzania and Kenya are almost polar opposites in terms of development models. Tanzania has taken perhaps the most radical departure from the legacy of political culture developed or imposed during the later years of British colonial rule. It is one of the few states in Africa where a serious effort has been made to translate the easy rhetoric of socialism into a concrete program of action. In contrast, too, with other states where the single dominant party has ei ther become moribund or been replaced by a military govern- ment, the dominant party -- TANU (or the Revolutionary Party, as it was restyled in 1977) -- has become the spearhead of mobilizing the citizenry with respect to the new society. Nyerere's version of development is labelled agrarian socialism. It recognizes the dual fact that upwards of ninety per cent of Tanzania's population lives in the rural areas and -- in the absence of sig- nificant mineral resources -- that the costs of modernization will ultimately come from the surplus from agricultural production. There are several key elements in Nyerere's program. The first is an emphasis upon increased crop production and processing of agricultural comodities at the expense of instant industrial ization. This is not a rejection of industrialization per se; it accepts the fact that industrialization is capital intensive and tends f to further aggravate the problems of urban unemployment. Secondly, as a matter both of social justice and economic efficiency, Nyerere' s program woul d di rect a significant portion of the profits of growth back to the rural sector. This would improve not only the means of production in the area of greatest promise but it would also improve the lot of those who are contributing most to development -- the rural peasant. The concrete manifestation of this policy is the implemen- tation of the ujamaa vi ji jini, or the villagization scheme. It has been the aim of TANU to get as many people as possible organized into self-help rural comnunities, where the services of government can be provided in a more efficient way and where the citizenry is provided with a mechanism for participating in decision-making on national development. Thirdly, Nyerere's program attempts to reduce the impact of historic and geographic accident which have contributed to the unequal distri- bution of the benefits of modernization. Hence, he has limited the salaries and other perquisites of the civil servants, lawyers and others who have had the privilege of a better education, and he has removed from the private sector such occupations as that of doctor, pri vate shopkeeper and others which contribute to the emergence of an incipient capitalist class. Also, in terms of "betting on the weak", he has attempted to redirect development funds to the regions of the country that were relatively neglected during the colonial era. Finally, Nyerere's social ism emphasizes self-reliance. This means not only that each person must contribute his full measure of talents to national development, but that the society must avoid becoming so dependent on external funds and personnel for development purposes, that one surrenders freedom to determine one's own fate. At the opposite end of the pole is Kenya, whose leadership in public proclaims a commitment to African social ism, but which in fact has provided one of the most vigorous examples of African development based upon massive infusions of external capi tal and personnel. A1 though its critics charge that Kenya has become subservient to the foreign capitalists upon whom the economy is dependent, Kenya leaders argue that the major directions of growth are determined by the state and not by foreigners, that Kenyans are coming into full control of the major economic enterprises, that the surpluses from growth allow for training programs which put Kenyans in positions of control in the economy, and that the ultimate test of an economy is how well it produces. On the last point, it is true that the growth rate in Kenya has been phenomenal. Kenya has witnessed not only industrial development but its improvement in the agricultural sector makes it a more effective competitor in the world market than Tanzania or Uganda. Kenyans claim, moreover, that the diversification of sources of external aid and personnel give no single power the ability to control events. However, it must be acknowledged that the benefits of development are distributed in a highly uneven fashion within Kenyan society. The major concentration of industrial growth has taken place in the vicinity of Nairobi, with some auxiliary development in and around the port of Mombasa. One ethnic group -- the Kikuyu -- have reaped an extra- ordinary share of the new wealth as great private fortunes are being made. The involvement of the masses in political and economic decision-making has been minimal, with KANU (Kenya African National Union) becoming more and more a machi ne party which serves the electoral and patronage objecti ves of the el i te. The ideological position of the third member of the community is difficult to classify. Uganda has undergone three changes of government since independence, and each represents a change in ideology. The first government, under the presi- dency of the Baganda Kabaka, reoresented a form of ideological neutrality as the leadership tried to balance the interests of the various historic kingdoms and the series of competitive parties. This gave way in 1966 to Mi1 ton Obote's brand of socialism within a highly centralized Uganda state, following the second exi le of Kabaka Mutesa and the collapse of Baganda separatism. A1 though Idi Amin since his coup of 1971 has retained the centralized state, one could hardly classi fy his frenetic and capricious brand of persona1 ized mil i tary rule as even an aberrant form of social ism. Reginald Green, a former economic adviser to Nyerere, has characteri zed Uganda development as a "commi tment to i negal i tarian , right-wi ng, xenophobic popul ism. "ZO Reasons of State. Even if the ideological commi tment of the three states had been the same, the pol i tical demands of each new society would in any event have resulted in some measure of separate development. Once the decision had been made to reject pol i tical integration within the framework of a coordinated independence program, i t became necessary to move rapidly in developing distinct national ins ti tu- tions and economic development plans within the three states. Each is a con- siderable entity ranging in size from Uganda's 91,134 square miles (roughly comparable to Pennsylvania) to Tanzania's 363,708 square miles (the size of Texas, Oklahoma and Louisiana), with Kenya's 224,960 (the size of Texas alone) placing it in between. They range in population from fourteen million in Tanzania, to twelve mill ion in Kenya, and ten mill ion in Uganda. The geographic development of each territory under colonial rule was very uneven, with northern areas of both Kenya and Uganda and the southeastern section of Tanganyika being relatively out of touch with the main economic, educational and political changes in their respective territories. Despite a1 1 the British pride in accomplishment, the educational systems under colonial rule did not leave behind a sizeable cadre of trained manpower to run the government, the economy, the universi tie:, the military and other institutions. The political system at the state level, f~rther- more, really only acquired significance for the African majority during the last few years or months of colonial rule. So unstable was each of the three East African political systems that it was only the hasty return of British paratroopers in 1964 that saved each of the regimes from rebellious military forces. With this in mind, it is understandable why two European observers of the East African scene concl uded in 1965 that the time was not ripe for pol i tical federation. They concluded that the problem had two main aspects: First, the 'political system' in each East African state -- its members, its modes of operation, its balance of power -- is new and only imperfectly understood by those who are operating it; and the dominant characteristic of politics is the extreme deli- cacy of the balance of forces which goes to make up the new pol i ti cal system, the extreme fragil i ty of the structures which the national leadership is creating for solving problems and mobi 1 i zing support for pol i cies . The leaders are cease1 essly preoccupied with the problem of sustaining the system so that re1 ations between di fferent groups can become more steadi ly and clearly defined, avenues of pol i tical action become legitimated, new elements admitted into the top leadership and old ones eased out -- a17 without fundamental crises . . . . In relation to this fundamental political fact the prospect of federating -- involving a partial surrender of sovereignty -- may introduce on the scene an unknown factor of unknown magnitude. No one knows what its effect on the system precariously emerging in their own country will turn out to be.21 The various schemes for East African federation did not envision the elimination of the state political apparatus; the leadership in Tanzania, for example, would still be responsible to that constituency within the East African conmuni ty which had only recently started to consider i tsel f Tanzanian rather than Chagga, Sukuma or Makonde. It would be the immediate, rather than the long-range, consequences of economic cooperation which would motivate the masses to suoport or reject the incumbent leadership at the state level. It would hardly provide satisfaction to the starving or the unemployed to inform them that an agricul tural processing industry could not be established within their district because that industry had been allocated to a neighboring country. Moreover, since it was firmly believed in Tanzania that money was a significant element in development, and since most of the money in East Africa seemed to be flowing to Kenya, the way to reverse the situation was for Tanzania to print its own currency, nationalize the banks and keep the money within Tanzania. Thus, it was not surprising to find the East African Currency Board going out of existence and each state being encouraged to set its own policies regarding money supplies, taxation and interest rates, as we1 1 as manipulating the economy for broad social, economic and political goals. Planning was to be carried out on a national basis, not regional. Simi larly, since doctors, engineers, 1 awyers and other professionals might tend to stay in the countries where they were trained rather than serving their countries of origin, it is perhaps also understandable why the agreement on assignment of separate teaching functions among Makerere Uni versi ty, the University of Dar es Salaam and the University of Nairobi hardly lasted till the ink was dry. The effective dissolution of the University of East Africa shortly after the Cormunity came into existence merely confirmed the reality of the situation, namely, that the national plans of each state projected differing needs for doctors to eradicate malaria, engineers to plan the construction of roads and dams, and lawyers to frame the unique legal system " developing in each country. Despi te the continued existence of an Inter-uni versi ty Commi ttee for East Africa, 1 ess than two hundred students were exchanged among the three states in 1974. The use of external examiners and the holding of joint research conferences are among the few remaining ves ti ges of educational cooperation. Divergences were also the product of the freedom of action available to each member to formulate external relations best suited to its own developmental, ideological or other interests. Outside the African context, Kenya -- in keeping with its modified capi talist development -- has very strong links with the West. Tanzania's approach to social ism makes it less fearful than its neighbors of relying heavily upon economic support from China. And Muslim General Amin -- politically isolated from most of his black African neighbors and the West -- has forged ties with the Arab world and revolutionary Libya, in particular. This complicates the problem of regional sol idari ty in dealing with world-wide and even continental issues. It also directly affects the economic future of the corrmon market since many of the trade arrangements link an East African state with a non-African economy. Tanzania, for example, must pay off its share of the Chinese loan for the Tanzara Railway by buying Chinese, rather than Kenyan, manufactured goods. In selling its cotton to Czechoslovakia, Uganda may be forced to buy Czech rather than Kenyan-made shoes. Indeed, the problems of regional sol idari ty are also affected by the separate relationships established by members of the Community with other African states. Nyerere, for example, has been one of Africa's most vigorous opponents of white rule in southern Africa and has insisted that liberation must remain hi~h his priority list regardless of any repercussions this may have on East African unity. Hence, he was prepared -- no matter what the cost to his involvement in the East African Comuni ty -- to lessen the dependence of Zambia on white- dominated Rhodesia and South Africa. The decision on the Tanzara Railway was negotiated without reference to Uganda and Kenya, which together with Tanzania coll ecti vely had administered the other rai 1 way sys tem in East Africa. Since there was already controversy regarding the cost of operating the existing East African railways, the Tanzara Railway had to be built and operated outside the East African Railways Corporation. The Kenyans may yet be proved correct that the new 1 ine is a "white elephant", particularly if independence of Mozambique, majority rule in Rhodesia (Zimbabwe), and the ending of civil strife in Angola lead the Zambians to reestablish their transit trade through the shorter rail 1 inks to the sea. In the meantime, a complication of the problem arose in 1974 when a quasi-private Kenyan transport firm had persuaded Zambia to have some of its exports and imports transported by road between Mombasa and Lusaka. The rationale for this was that the crowded conditions and escalat- ing surcharges at Dar es Salaam harbor demanded an alternative route. This arrangement, however, clearly threatened the ul timate fiscal sol vency of the Tanzara Railway and the new port facilities at Dar es Salaam. In addition, it put an additional financial burden on Tanzania, since it was its roads which were being severely damaged by the heavy trucks transporting the copper and oil .22 It was this situation which led the Tanzanians to temporarily close the border with Kenya in 1974 and at periodic intervals thereafter until the "permanent sealing" in 1977. The completion of the Tanzara Railway and the improved efficiency of Dar es Salaam cargo hand1 ing led the Zambians them- selves to abandon road transhipment through Mombasa. Indeed, by 1976 Dar Es Salaam was actually handling more tonnage than Mombasa and over eighty per cent of Zambia's copper was being exported from the Tanzanian port. Hence a con- siderable economic a1 1 iance was diverting Tanzania's attention southward, away from its common market neighbors. Common Services Corporations. A number of the organizations which jointly served the three states fell victim to the demands of political sovereignty once independence had been achieved. In this category was the early demise of the East African Navy, the High Court of Appeals, the University of East Africa and -- somewhat later -- the Currency Board. Certain other agencies which lacked an elaborate infrastructure were more easily dissolved as soon as one or more of the partners decided there was more to be gained by operating separately rather than jointly. Such was the fate of the Tourist Association. There were a few common services, such as the railways, harbors, the air 1 ine and postal services, where it was initial ly assumed that the costs of separate operations by each state would be prohibitive and the benefits of collaboration were substantial. Consequently, the partners agreed not only to continue co- operation in these areas, but actually to expand the enterprises. Each partner, unfortunately, tended to view the functioning of the comnon services from a national perspective. Uganda and Tanzania, the two economical ly Doorer members, expected that the more profitable Kenya operations of the rail- roads, airways, harbors and other enterprises would pay for the development of services in those areas which had been relatively neglected during the colonial era. .Conversely, the Kenyans chafed at having to subsidize what they regarded as the less efficiently managed and less productive operations in Tanzania and Uganda. Fiscal affairs also plagued the functioning of the corporations. Accord- ing to the original formula each partner state was to share in the cost of operating the services, and the locally collected revenues of each corporation were to be forwarded to its central headquarters. Here again, however, Tanzania and Uganda found themselves at a disadvantage. The headquarters of the two largest corporations -- Railways and Airways -- were located in Nairobi, and the conflict with General Amin delayed both the establishment of the Develop- ment Bank in Kampala and the transfer of Post and Telecommunications to that city. Tanzania did have one revenue-earning corporation with the relocation of the Harbours Corporation in Dar es Salaam. Its second operational head- quarters -- that of the Economic Community at Arusha -- did not entai 1 significant revenue transfers from the other two states. Thus, the imbalance of payments within the Community, which was already distorted in favor of the superior Kenyan trading position, was further aggravated by the transfer of corporation revenues to Nai robi . Whi le Tanzania's re1 uctance to transfer funds was largely economic and related to the fluctuations in the value of the Tanzanian shill ing, Uganda's obstinacy was more overtly pol i tical. General Amin used the revenues issue as a form of hostage in his efforts to secure his official recognition as Uganda chief of state by Nyerere. In any event the . fai 1 ure of revenue transfers 1 eft the corporations with serious cash flow problems in meeting payrolls and purchasing fuel. The failure of the govern- ments to contribute their pledged assessments, moreover, prevented the -epai rs and rep1 acement of obsolete equipment. The East African Rai lways Corporation was the first of the corporations to encounter the threat of dissolution. The three states quarreled about the scarcity of rolling stock, which Tanzania and Uganda charged was being kept in Kenya for more profitable runs. Tanzania objected, moreover, to the freight from the Arusha-Moshi area of Tanzania being shipped out of Mombasa instead of contributing to the further development of the port facilities at Dar es Salaam. Even more irritating to the Tanzanians was the diversion of some of the more profitable rai 1 road cargo to the quasi -state Kenatco trucking firm in which rnany Kenyan pol i ticians had substantial personal interests. Faced with the refusal of the other two states to transfer corporation revenues to Nairobi, Kenya attempted to deal with the problem by insisting that a1 1 service on the Kenya portion of the rai 1 roads be paid for in Kenya currency. This was a harsh blow to landlocked Uganda whose economy was in dire straights under General Amin. Tanzania, however, was able to retaliate by ha1 ting all passenger service to Kenya in February 1975 and later that year removed sections of the track, thereby bringing a1 1 inter-terri torial freight service to a halt as well. From that point onward the railroads ceased to operate as a coordi nated enterpri se, the headquarters of the corporation was di ssol ved and the only discussions which took place thereafter were over the distribution of the rolling stock, the lake steamers and other assets as well as the parcel 1 i ng out of responsi bi 1.i ty for the debt service. A similar fate befell the Harbours Corporation, which had hived off from the Railways in 1969, with the headquarters being moved from Mombasa to Dar es Salaam. Kenyans were upset with having to use revenues collected at the more profitable Mombasa port to retire the World Bank loan for the expansion of facilities at Dar es Salaam. It was particularly annoying since the Kenyans felt that they should have had a second port of their own to relieve congestion at Mornbasa. In this instance it was Kenya that refused to remit revenues of the corporation to i ts headquarters in Tanzania. By mi d-1976 the controversy had led to the decision that each country would operate its own port facilities, and a year later Tanzania froze the bank accounts of the corporation and fired the Kenyan and Ugandan employees. The demise of the corporation was complicated by the fact that international loans to the Community were premised on the continuation of regional cooperation in operating the seaports. The hi story of the Posts and Telecomnunications Corporation fol lowed a similar course. The dispute with Amin was not merely an inter-governmental controversy; the Kenyan and Tanzanian employees of the Corporation objected to having to live in the climate of fear which pervaded the Uganda capital. The Kenyan and Tanzanian governments a1 i ke were re1 uctant to transfer corporati on funds to Uganda, which was experiencing spiraling inflation under Arnin's erratic economic pol icies. Ul timately each country began printing and sell ing its own stamps and handling its own telegraphic services. In any event, the difficulties experienced by both the railways and the airways made the coordinated shipment of mail and parcel post impossible to accomplish. The coup de qrace to the aspirations for unity, however, was the demise of the East African Airways and the events preceding and following the decision. A1 though Airways had frequently operated at a deficit, as recently as 1974 it enjoyed a period of record-breaking profits. Given the high cost of each country purchasing separate equipment and paying the salaries of pilots and other professional staff, it was long predicted that Airways had the best prospects for survi val within the Comnuni ty. There were, however, long-stand- ing controversies over both its foreign and domestic operations. Tanzania and Uganda, which have the more impressive game parks in East Africa, had chafed at the fact that over eighty per cent of the international flights were directed in and out of Nairobi. Thus, the mounting number of camera safaris would book tours and accomodations in Kenya and travel by private vehicles to the game parks in the neighboring states. Not only did this mean that most of the tourist revenues remained in Kenya, but it meant that Tanzania's impressive international airport at Moshi -Arusha and Uganda ' s Entebbe airport were almost redundant. A further aggravation with East African Airways was Tanzania's insistence that the more profitable international service should help subsidize the network of feeder runs which were regarded as vital factors in maintaining internal com- munications and trade in the largest of the three states. As in the case of the other corporations, the crisis with Airways came to a head over the issue of revenue transfers to the headquarters in Nairobi and the shared responsi bi 1 i ty of purchasing new equipment. Al though the demise came in stages, by February 1977 Airways was formally dissolved after thirty years of existence. Each state scrambled to retain whatever equipment and assets of the corporation were physically present in the country at the time of dissolution. Kenya was left with the unpaid bills of the corporation, and during the ensuing months great wrangling took place over the distribution of the assets and debt obligations. In the meantime Kenya and Uganda each set up sep~rate national airlines, and Tanzania turned southward to Mozambique and secured a bilateral agreement to establish and operate a single public airline. This further accelerated the redirection of Tanzania's economic interests away from the East African Communi ty . With the non-functioning or formal demise of the Comuni ty corporations, all that has remained of system-wide institutions has been the General Fund Services. This comprises the Central Secretariat, which continues to function in Arusha and has responsibility for meteorology, customs and research on industrial development, natural resources and medicine. The Fate of the Comon Market Arranaements The compl emen tary feature to the Communi ty ' s techni cal servi ces corpora- tions has been the common market arrangements. The Treaty which was fashioned at Arusha in 1967 was to be the lynch-pin in the quest for political unity via the functional route. Indeed, the enthusiasm of the three East African partners was so infectious that several of the neighboring states almost im- mediately applied for membership or registered an interest in an expanded economic communi ty i n eastern Africa. Of the three participants, Kenya stood to gain the most from the common market arrangements, thus counterbalancing the advantage in benefits that the other two states were to have received from an upgrading of the technical services. The edge which Kenya enjoyed in industrial growth under colonial rule would be further enhanced by its ready access to markets close at hand. Its economic hegemony within East Africa could further serve as a springboard for the establishment of even more significant markets I in Zambia, Zaire and even West Africa as we1 1 as the expansions of non-African trade I and investment 1 inkages. The 1967 Treaty, nevertheless, was designed to be of benefit to all three parties by permitting the less developed partners to improve their industrial standing I relative to Kenya. The decision, however, to locate the Community headquarters at Arusha -- the geographic center of East Africa -- did little to counteract the I economic dominance of Nairobi. Foreign investors, the World Bank, American aid and foundation officials and others early recognized that Nairobi was the vital center, whereas Arusha had lost even the dynamism it had enjoyed in the later 1 days of the colonial era. Efforts to redress the trade imbalance within the Comnuni ty consisted ( primarily of giving monopolies in certain manufacturing fields to Tanzania and Uganda to protect thei r fledgl ing industries. The arrangements did not work. I Kenya early violated the agreement to leave the textile industry to the other two states, and even in the agricultural sector Kenyan production was becoming 1 more efficient in those key areas, such as sisal and coffee, where the other two 1 had enjoyed the competitive edge. Kenya complained that the two neighbors abused the transfer tax arrangements whereby tari ffs were 1 evied against Kenya industrial products to protect fledgl ing enterprises. By 1975 the situation had so deteriorated that Tanzania began to prohibit the importation of any goods from Kenya that could be manufactured in Tanzania even if Tanzanian firms could not meet the domestic demand. The duplication of industrial functions had been further accelerated by resort to exchange controls , the imposition of import licensing and the use of industrial licensing in proliferating activities which could have more efficiently been confined to a single factory.23 By the mid-1970s the erosion of the free trade aspect of the Communi ty was plainly apparent. Instead of the three states becoming each other's best customers, imports and exports among the three had suffered a drastic decline during the first half of the decade. In 1975 alone, the Tanzanian exports to its East African partners suffered a decline of 39 per cent from the 1974 situation, with a roughly similar slide in its imports from Uganda and Kenya. The deterioration in relations with President Amin and the "permanent sealing" of the Kecya-Tanzanian border in 1977 could bring the inter-trade relationship among the three close to the zero point. The three former partners are clearly looking elsewhere for economic ties. Tanzania, in addition to the long-term link with China resulting from the Tanzara Railway loan, is shifting its attention southward in Africa, fashioning stronger bonds with Zambia and Mozambi~ue. Kenya, now cut off from its road links with Zambia and Zaire, is casting its economic net on a worldwide basis, with Mexico, Japan and other non-African states figuring prominently in its trade and investment patterns along with other African states outside the eastern Africa region. Uganda has become more and more reliant on aid and trade with Russia, Libya and an assortment of other states. If the problems of the comnon market were dealt with in purely economic terms, it would be apparent that all three countries are the losers by the break-up of the East African Comuni ty. Each state is faced with the prospect of a balance of payments problem as its foreign reserves are drained to the more industrial ized areas of the world rather than remai ni ng wi thin East Africa. The demise of cooperation in the transport field and the search for ext~rnal economic links has increased the ultimate cost of both imported and exported products -- a situation further aggravated by the increased price of oil. Finally, the failure of trade and transportation within the region has contributed substantially to the inflationary spiral in each of the three countries. Prospects for the Future of East African Unity It became all too apparent that if the East African Community were to achieve even its more 1 imi ted goal of economic cooperation -- to say nothing of its larger goal of political federation -- there had to be some sacrifices made with respect to state sovereignty. The Community needed an authority that could act independently of the total membership. While not lamenting the passing of colonial rule, this is precisely what the imperial government provi ded the region prior to i ndependence. Whenever the del i berati ons among the three colonial governors had reached an impasse, the Colonial Office could step in and provide a solution, however unsatisfactory it may have been to one or more of the parties. The colonial system was able to stimulate growth in selected areas, based on the needs of the British empire as a whole. The system could also work in reverse. That is, a territory might be prevented from developing a crop or an industry which would put it into competition with another territory within the colonial system. Since independence, no super- territorial authority has been able to impose cooperation. The rule of unanimity which obtained in the operation of the various insti- tutions within the East African Community, moreover, was not likely to be surrendered easi ly, given the state of underdevelopment in Tanzania, the vagaries of the military regime in Uganda and the re1 uctance of the Kenyans to have their 1 imi ted prosperity subsidize what they regarded as the mismanaged or ideological ly misguided economies of their two neighbors. Any national regime in Kenya, Tanzania or Uganda which voted to surrender a portion of its sover- eignty might find itself threatened with ouster at the first sign of economic hardship for its people. The history of events in East Africa seems to confirm that there must be a constant momentum forward and a continuing surrender of state authority in increasingly complex areas -- if only to preserve existing achievements in cooperation. East African leaders since independence have faced a considerably more difficul t situation than that faced by American leaders in 1787 or West European statesmen at the end of the Second World War. Instead of the East African economies being basically complementary, they are competitive with respect to their main source of production, agricul ture. They lacked, moreover, complementarity with respect to the basic ingredients of industrialization, which proved to be the initial binding element in West European cooperation. Instead of closing the industrial gap which had given Kenya a relative advantage over its neighbors, the gap had considerably widened. Each was compelled, by virtue of the diversity of its external trade commi tments and investment opportuni ties, to engage in transactions which weakened, rather than strengthened, regional economic unity. Indeed, no real effort had been made to engage in regional economic planning, despite the provision for it in the 1967 Treaty. Far from breaking down the separate nationalist feelings, each state had been pursuing a different approach to national language policy and the development of disparate symbols of nationalism. Attempts to develop a common citizenship remained dormant. Even the efforts to develop a regional ci vi 1 service committed to East African cooperation were undermined by delays in transferri ng the headquarters of Posts and Telecommuni cations to Uganda, the expulsion of Kenya workers on East African Railways assignment in Tanzania and other acts which made few want to risk the relative security of national employment. Even before the closing of the borders, the erection of customs and irrmi gration checkpoints at each inter-terri torial crossing, moreover, hindered the free flow of individuals throughout the region. No country was immune to demands that "foreign Africans" be expelled to provide more jobs for the local population. Certainly there was no group of "federationists" who could politically challenge the leadership of the three separate states. What could have reversed this process of retrogression? Perhaps inter- nal changes in one or more of the member states coul d have provided the basis for closer cooperation. One could not pin much hope on the three states achieving a level of economic parity through the pursuit of nationally- directed economic plans; therefore, the changes would had to have been pol i tical . This could have come about, for example, through the emergence of a more social ist-oriented leadership in Kenya, through Tanzania adopting a 1 ess antagonistic attitude towards capi tal ist development or through Uganda being 1 iberated from the personalized rule of General Amin. A1 ternati vely , increased cooperation could have been the consequence of external pressures, such as a military threat to the freedom of the three states, from whatever source. Indeed, the closest thing to external pressure ws the decision of the World Bank in 1976 to suspend its $50 mill ion worth of loan: to the Community after Uganda had reportedly withheld its portion of the repay- ments. It was unofficially hinted that the move was calculated to pressure the three states to improve relations with each other. The effort of the World Bank, however, was both muted and short-lived, and it eventually lifted the suspension wi thout a substantial change in relations among the three partners. One further mechani sm which might have contributed to successful functional integration would have been the expansion of the Community along the lines envisioned in the 1967 Treaty. This might have led to a reduction of tensions among the original participants. The inclusion of Zambia, for example, might have had the dual effect of convincing the Kenyans that another relatively prosperous state would be making a contribution to the development of poorer areas while at the same time reassuring Tanzania through the inclusion of an ally who is closer to itself both in ideology and commi tment to southern African 1 i beration. The addition of Malawi, Zaire, Rwanda, Burundi, Ethiopia and Soma1 ia could conceivably have led to a relaxation of the unanimi ty rule in decision-making. Unanimity is more difficult to achieve in a union of only three members, when there is the possi bi 1 i ty of two partners forming a continu- ing coalition against the third. There might have been one drawback. The broader-gauged approach, which is currently being considered by fifteen states i n West Af ri ca , woul d perhaps have 1 imi ted cooperation to economi c and techni cal matters for some time to come. Increasing the diversity of the Community would have diminished even further the prospects for an early consideration of pol i tical federation. Until the break-up of the East African Airways Corporation in February of 1977, there were many who continued to take great comfort in small things regarding the prospects for regional integration. After all, the leaders of the three East African states continue even today to make pub1 ic pronouncements regardi ng thei r commi tmen t to the concept of uni ty . Despi te the fai 1 ure of the heads of state to meet as the collective executive of the Community since October 1971 there had, nevertheless, been frequent meetinas of officials at the ministerial level. The Ministers of Finance as we11 as the ministers in charge of power and communications, for example, met at fairly frequent inter- val s. There have even been bilateral negotiations between Kenyan and Tanzanian officials following the demise of the joint airways. None but the most blatant optimists, however, could assume that it was possible to reconstitute the East African comnunity in the form that it existed at independence or at the signing of the Treaty of 1967. The Theoreti cal Si gni fi cance of the East African Experience Adrni ttedly some of the experience with functional integration in East Africa is sui generis and has no relevance to the analysis ri efforts elsewhere to achieve a higher plane of cooperation among previously autonomous pol i tical units. There are, however, a number of general propositions which do emerge from this study which may have significance for students interested in the problems of trans-national integration. Proposition 1 ("Mutual Benefits") : A1 though in the initial states of integra- tion, one or more partners may be willing to forego immediate advantages or even to suffer minor disadvantages, in the long run there must be steady, demonstra- ble and substantial benefits to the major units in the partnership in order to sustain integrative efforts. Proposi tion 2 ("Qua1 i ty of Cooperation") : In functional integration the qua1 i ty of cooperative efforts (that is, the critical importance of the activity to the participants and the degree of increased interdependence and compl ementari ty it establishes) is more important than the mere quantitative increase in the number of areas of cooperation. Proposition 3 ("Dynamic Process") : Functional integration is a dynamic process which requires continuous forward movement into new and related areas of coopera- tion in order to prevent the initial areas of cooperation from becoming politicized in terns of the separate interests of the participating states. Proposition 4 ("Irrevocable Transactions") : Functional integration which is designed to lead to political unity must be based upon transactions which are by their nature irrevocably binding on the ~ol units involved. Proposition 5 ("Numbers and Relative Strenpth") : In any integrative effort which goes beyond 1 imi ted cooperation in narrow1 \,J specified areas, the number of participating units and their strength relative to one another become critical to the sustained success of the venture. Proposition 6 ("Shifting Coalitions"): In cases of increasingly complex func- tional integration, there must be sufficient diversity to enable the formation of shifting coalitions on major issues. On each new issue there must at least be the presumption that any one of the partners could serve as a potential a1 ly. Proposition 7 ("Supra-national Authority" ) : Sustained functional integration requires the existence of a supra-national institution having authority to make binding decisions on a basis other than unanimity rule. Proposi tion 8 (" Indi vi dual and Group Contacts ") : Functional i ntegration desi gned to lead to pol i tical integration must go beyond intergovernmental relationships and involve significant and sustained contact among private individuals and groups which transcend pol i ti cal boundaries. Proposition 9 (" Increased Inner Direction") : Functional integration designed to lead to pol i tical integration requires that increasingly the importance of the collective effort to each of the participating units comes to outweigh the importance attached by the members to external pol i tical units and relationships. Proposition 10 ("Ideological Compatabil i ty"): Functional integration is neutral wi th respect to i deol ogy. Functional integration, however, cannot proceed where the ideol ogical divergences among the participating units regarding strategies of development, participatory democracy and other issues are too basic to the areas in which cooperation is being pursued. END NOTES 1 Alexander Hetherwi ck, "Nyasaland Today and Tomorrow," Journal of the African Society 17 (1917) : 11-19; 'Africanus' (Frederick Melland), "A Central African Confederation," Journal of the African Society 17: (July, 1918) : 276-306. 2 Harry Johnston, Story of My Life (London: Chatto and Hindus, 1923). 3 Kenneth Ingham, A History of East Africa (New York: Praeger, 1962), pp. 310 ff. 4 C.F. Andrews, The Indian Question in East Africa (Nairobi: Swift Press, 19?1), pp. 6-7. 5 Report of the East Africa Comnission, Cmd. 2387 (1925). 6 Report of the Comnission on Closer Union of the Dependencies in Eastern and Central Africa, Cmd. 3234 (1929). 7 Joint Select Cornmi ttee on Closer Union in East Africa, Report and Minutes of Evidence: 1930-31, 2 vols. (London: HMSO, 1931). 8 Sir Donald Cameron, My Tanganyika Service and Some Nigeria (London: Allen and Unwin, 1939), passim. 9 For a discussion of the shifting settler attitudes on closer union and other subjects, see the 1 i vely correspondence between two Engl i sh women in El speth Huxley and Margery Perham, Race and Politics in Kenya (London: Faber, rev. ed. 1955). 10 Ingham, A History of East Africa, pp. 314-320. 11 Ibid., pp. 375-376. 12 Colonial Office Paper No. 191 (London: HIISO, 1945). 13 Jane Banfiel d, "The Structure and Admini stration of the East African Common Services Organization ," in Col in Leys and Peter Robson, eds . , Federation in East Africa: Opportunities and Problems (London: Oxford University Press, 14 David Apter, The Political Kingdom in Uganda (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1967 ), pp. 276-288. 15 Anthony Hughes, "Communi ty of Disinterest," Africa Report 20 (March/Apri 1, 1975) : 37-38. 16 Cameron, My Tanqanyika Service, pp. 224-225. 17 Banfield, "Structure and Administration," pp. 30-40. 18 Cf. Donald Rothchild, Pol i tics of Integration: An East Africa Documentary (Nairobi : East African Pub1 ishing House, 1967), passim. 19 B.U.T. Muthari ka, Toward Mu1 tinational Economic Cooperation in Africa (New York: Praeger, 1972), pp. 267 ff. 20 "East African Comrnuni ty -- 1975 and After," Africa Contemporary Record, 1975-76, p. A59. 21 Leys and Robson, Federation in East Africa, pp. 185-186. 22 Hughes, "Community of Disinterest," pp. 37-43. 23 Philip Ndegwa, The Common Market and Development in East Africa (Nairobi : East African Publishing House, 1965), pp. 136-148. THE ORIGINS OF EOU?/DARY COI!FLICT IN AFRICA J. Barron Boyd Jr., LeMoyne College Because boundaries define an important segment of the environment with- in which decision makers must function, they have had a mu1 ti faceted and complex impact upon the dynamics of African foreign policy. Boundaries in Africa have served the traditional , geopol i tical role of partially determin- ing the capabil i ties, resources and perhaps even power which the African states can employ in support of their foreign pol icy.] Boundaries define the extent of territory under the sovereign control of a group of decision makers and the presence of certain non-human components of the power equa- tion will depend upon the qua1 ity or character of that territory included within the national boundaries. The natural resources at a state's disposal, the ease or difficulty with which it can engage in intercourse with the rest of the world, the presence or absence of natural barriers against invasion, the heterogeneity or homogeneity of the state's population, to mention but a few characteristics, are all determined by the shape and location of its physical boundaries. This function of boundaries is obviously not unique to Africa and holds equally in a1 1 areas of the world. The factors which make the role of boundaries in African foreign pol icy particularly worthy of note and inves ti- gation derive from the process by which the contemporary African borders were defined and the rather unique set of pressures which are consequently present in the foreign pol icy environment of the African states. The importance of boundary re1 ated issues in African international re1 a- tions is often attributed to the supposed arbitrary and artificial nature of the continent's modern terri torial boundaries. It has frequently been maintained that the states which now dot the continent were created during the great scramble for Africa by a1 ien diplomats who knew 1 i ttle of, and cared less for, the social, political and topographical realities of Africa. European diplomats were comnonly depicted sitting about green baize tab1 es in their respective capitals with ruler and blue pencil in hand carving up the continent without regard for the disruptive effects that their efforts at partition would have on Africa. For example, Lord Salisbury, in a humorous rnomen t, observed that We have been engaged in drawing 1 ines upon maps where no white man's foot ever trod; we have been giving away moun- tains and rivers and lakes to each other, only hindered by the small impediment that we never knew exactly where the mountains and rivers and lakes were.2 The ramifications of these actions are seldom depicted in such a humorous manner. To the contrary, parti tion grouped together peoples who shared lit- tle sense of common identity, separated ethnic and linguistic proups whose traditional patterns of trade and interaction were thereby disrupted by a relatively impermeable barrier, and created political units whose size and composition were in some cases incompatible with the goals of economic and pol i tical development. On the basis of this boundary artificiality, many authors have postu- lated that colonialism laid the base for frequent conflict between the ~frican states once they gained their independence.3 In particular, it was felt that after independence the African communi ty would be plagued with efforts by the indi vi dual states to readjust the boundaries, through forceful means if neces- sary, to make them more congruent with the ethnographic landscape. The fol- lowing observation by I. William Zartman is typical of the viewpoint which prevai led during the early and mid-1960s: Any African state can have boundary problems if it wants. The newness of African states and the frequent i rrelevance of their geographic frames to their economic, social and political lives make the continent more potentially sus- cepti ble to territorial disputes than any other.4 Because of the obvious importance of boundary disputes in an environment where, because of the colonial legacy, "any state can have boundary problems if it wants," a thorough and systematic evaluation of the forces which lead to boundary conflict would be an important project in itself; but since there are several other issues of more general importance which are linked to the dynamics of boundary conflict, such an investigation would be of wider rele- vance. As we have menti oned, contemporary African boundary confl i cts are often felt to be a direct and immediate product of the continent's colonial heritage. If Africa's modern boundaries had been allowed to evolve in a more natural manner, or if the colonial powers had based their parti tion on a more thor- ough appreciation of the socio-cul tural mosaic of the area, it is assumed that the international environment in Africa would be less conducive to boundary disputes. A systematic empirical study of the origins of boundary conflict in Africa would therefore help to indicate the extent to which current prob- lems on :he continent are 1 inked to the colonial past. Moreover, because boundary related foreign pol icy is a part of the over- all phenomenon of African foreign policy formulation, an assessment of the factors which serve as a catalyst to the outbreak of territorial conflict could indirectly indicate some of the more general causes of intra-African conflict. An analysis of the dynamics of boundary conflict could at least provide some interesting hypotheses about why African states fight. Boundaries and Forei gn Pol icy Pol i tical boundaries mark sharp discontinuities in pol i tical jurisdiction. No matter what the degree of physical proximity of individuals on either side of the boundary 1 ine, the fact that a political border separates them means that their national political orientations, duties and obligations will be sharply divergent. When the national pol i tical environment does not coincide with traditional patterns of ethnic affinity, subnational political contact or traditional forms of social and economic relations, some disruption will be the result. This disruption will occur because both the ethnic group and the national government will be placing simul taneous and often confl icting demands-- for respect, primary a1 legiance, deference, etc. -- upon the people. While the central government may have a monopoly on the use of coercive means to force the people to give it primary loyalty, ethnic ties may be deeply in- grained and difficult to break. As a consequence of the fact that such cross- cutting and sometimes irreconci lab1 e pressures are placed upon them, some disruption will plague the people. When discussing the relationship between political boundaries and those of the socio-cul tural setting, it has been customary to make a distinction between antecedent, consequent and superimposed boundaries.5 Antecedent boundaries are those which are establ i shed before human settlement patterns are establ ished, and therefore before the socio-cul tural environment of a state has coalesced. The disruptive effects of such political boundaries are at a minimum for their antecedent status will insure that they play a major role in gui di ng and shaping the evol ution of subsequent socio-cul tural group- ings. Because the political boundaries are established before the people arrive, they will play an integral part in determining what patterns of interaction will develop at a later time. Consequent boundaries are those which are established after human set- tlement patterns, affinity groups, markets and other relationships have sol idified, but this type of boundary coi nci des with those socio-cul tural patterns. Uhen one refers to natural boundaries, it is generally this type which is cited. Like antecedent boundaries, consequent ones have a low potential for disruption since the political and socio-cul tural environments mesh. The final category in this crude typology is the superimposed form of boundary. Superimposed boundaries are simi 1 ar to consequent ones i n the sense that they are developed, or imposed, after the soci o-cul tural en\.i ron- ment is solidified but the crucial difference between the two is that super- imposed boundaries do not mesh with the out1 ines of the socio-cul tural setting. When boundaries are of the superimposed type, ethnic groups are often bisected by pol i ti cal boundaries, and competitive or hostile social enti ties are often 1 umped together within the same administrative or political jurisdiction. When this is the case, the disruption mentioned earlier can be expected to pose a problem for both the affected individuals and the central government. As most African boundaries are of the superimposed type, and as it is this form of pol i tical boundary which causes the greatest discontinuity be- tween the pol i tical and socio-cul tural frames of reference for the people, the domestic disruption in Africa can be expected to reach severe levels. Sirni larly, because the bisection of ethnic groups by national boundaries pl aces part of the same group in different states, the presence of superimposed boundaries can have international imp1 ications as well. However, to agree that superimposed boundaries like those in Africa will cause domestic and perhaps transnational disruption is not sufficient to specify the manner in which this disruption is translated into the policy of the various states. It is not boundaries per which cause conflict, but rather it is state pol- icy which causes it. And while the friction which is a product of artificial, superimposed boundaries may be a factor which goes into the generation of con- flict, it is only one of the many stimuli which help determine the course of a state's policy. In order to more ful ly understand the relationship between the presence of superimposed boundaries and African foreign pol icy confl ict the following strategy will be adopted. First, an effort will be made to present a number of possible explanations for the outbreak of boundary confl ict. These possible explanations are derived fron a thorough overview of the existing literature on boundary conflict and as such represent the "traditional wisdom" on the topic. Unfortunately, this traditional wisdom does not provide us with the clear answers which we seek for the explanations it offers are complex, con- fusing and often contradictory. Therefore in order to more effectively determine the validity of such propositions an attempt will be made to use modern methods of data analysis to test them with data derived from the actual behavior of the African states. One manifestation of boundary related conflict has a purely domestic impact. Upon having their traditional patterns of socio-cul tural relation- ships disrupted by the superimposi tion of pol i tical boundaries (first by the colonial powers and later by the modern independent African states which adopted the colonial divisions of the continent with 1 i ttle a1 teration) , the affected domestic groups can be expected to make demands upon the govern- ment for alleviation of the disruption. Such demands can take various forms ranging from pressure to relax the sanctions against free movement across the border to calls for cession of the affected territory to another state. But no matter what form the demands take, the aim is to elicit a change in government pol icy to permit the continuation of traditional patterns of re- lations. When faced with such demands, the central government has essential ly two options in domestic policy: it can ignore its vested interest in main- taining the sanctity of the borders and increase its permeability, or it can attempt to strictly enforce the present boundaries hoping that eventual ly ethnic boundaries will come to conform to the national ones. Given the jealousy with which many African states guard the trappings of sovereignty after the prolonged colonial domi nation, and the potential chain reaction of separatist claims which might be set off by acquiescence to any particu- lar ethnic group's demands, the second option seems to be the most likely solution. The result of attempting to force closure of the border is, if feelings run deep enough, some form of domestic confl ict. This same basic pattern of demands can have international as well as domestic ramifications when none of the above options are available to the acting state. If the challenged government is reluctant to allow the per- meabil i ty of its borders to increase and is simultaneously unwill ing, or unable, to apply domestic sanctions, it has the option of trying to ease domestic demands through foreign pol icy pressure on other states .6 The aim of the government which adopts this tactic is to adjust the boundary through pressure on a neighboring foreign power. The emergence of this pattern of interstate conflict is generally predicated upon the existence of a situation where ethnic groups are bisected by state boundaries with parts of the same group being placed on either side of a state border. This phenomenon is termed ethnic population overhang. The proposition that such ethnic population overhang is a cata- lyst to international conflict on territorial issues is perhaps one of the most obvious and s traight-forward explanations of the 1 inkage between boundary artificiality and conflict, and it has received a great deal of support in the 1 i terature. 7 The following comment by a student of African boundary problems is typical of the importance attached to the ethnic population overhang hypothesis, "... the commonest situation in Africa [is] to find ethnic groups who wish to be united with their fellow men across the border and whose de- sires are used by the government to justify boundary changes. "8 The Horn of Africa is felt to be one area where the overhang effect has been most pronounced and hence where it has had the most impact upon boundary conflict. As a result of the colonial parti tion of Africa the Somal i people were widely dispersed throughout the entire Horn area. While the Somal i Republic is the center of Somali habitation, members of this general ethnic group also occupy extensive territory in both Kenya and Ethiopia. It would seem that as a basic consequence of this severe ethnic fragmentation (itself a product of the colonial partition of the continent) the Somali government has issued claims on some 80,000 square miles of Ethiopian and 45,000 square mi 1 es of Kenyan terri tory since gai ni ng independence. While there are, as we shall see in subsequent pages, many facets to this problem, Somal ia's irredentist claims to Kenyan and Ethiopian territory have been based upon a cultural rationale. The Somali Republic claimed that since the colonial divisions of Africa were an archaic legacy which had little relevance for modern African national i sm, the Soma1 i people coul d not be considered fully independent unti 1 that legacy was eradicated and a1 1 Soma1 i people were united under the same political jurisdiction. In support of their claims to territory the government of the Somali Republic maintained at the Pan African Summit of 1963 that all Somalis were members of a single Somali nation, Somali is our language, spoken from the Gulf of Aden to the Northern Frontier District [of Kenya]. Islam is our culture, pastoralism our way of life. We want to reunite with our brothers with whom we can evolve an administration suited to our way of life.9 As rnioht be expected, Somali claims to Kenyan and Ethiopian territory were not welcomed by the governments of those states and political friction ensued. In the period between the early 1960s and the present the Horn of Africa has been the scene of much boundary related conflict as the Somalis continued to level claims to territory and Kenya and Ethiopia reacted to those c1 aims. Many authors have isolated this situation and asserted that it is the most overt and obvious manifestation of Africa's artificial boundaries lead- ing to the fragmentation of an ethnic group which in turn resulted in boundary confl ict between the several affected states. For example: The circumstances of Kenya's connections with Somalia and many of the conflicts and problems which beset the Horn are founded in the present day distribution of Somali speaking peoples and in the ways in which they have become di vi ded among several different states and powers. The anomalies and inconsistencies of territorial boundaries in north east Africa provide classic examples of the problems which arise with a strong sense of na- ti onal uni ty among a peopl e who have been di vi ded among several different territories in the past .lo While the Horn area may be the most noted example, the impact of ethnic popu- lation overhang is not confined to that region. The disputes between Ghana and Togo (1956-1966) also seem to have been a product, at least partially, of ethnic population overhang. During the period of colonialism the Ewe ethnic group was divided between British and French jurisdictions. With the coming of independence the Ewe national ist leaders in the former French territory of Togo claimed the Ewe occupied territory in formerly British Ghana. Initial ly the Togolese based thei r claims on cultural criteria maintaining that they, 1 ike the Somalis, sought to reunify the Ewe group. When this argument proved to lack support in international and African forums, the government a1 tered its tactics and used an historical argument to buttress their claims. During the period of German colonial occupation the Togolands were uni ted, and it was this boundary configuration that the Togolese asserted shoul d be the bas i s for post- i ndependence boundaries . Ghana, then led by Nkrurnah, did not accept Togolese claims to its ter- ritory and in fact turned Togo's argument around. Since Ghana was then strong- ly committed to Pan African, anti -colonial ideology, Nkrumah coul d not easily argue that the colonial borders were sacrosanct. He therefore chose to counter- attack from a Pan African position. He asserted that the best way for the Ewes to be reunited was by union with Ghana. A Ghanaian annexation of Togo would thus both remove a potentially disruptive boundary problem and be con- sistent with Nkrumah's interpretation of Pan Africanist dogma. While the boundary conflict was raised to a higher level-- that of a debate over ideology-- the initial catalyst for conflict lay in the ethnic population overhang be- tween the two states and the demands placed upon the government of Togo as a result of that situation by the Ewes. These are but two of the many examples of territorial conflict which seem related to ethnic population overhang.ll However, as these cases are more thoroughly investigated, it often appears that other factors have at 1 east equal importance i n the generation of boundary confl ict. One of these factors is the degree of ethnic homogeneity which obtains in the domestic environment of the conflict prone state. It has been sug- gested that domestic pressure on a government will be more 1 i kely to el ici t a response of foreign policy conflict if the acting state is not ethnically fragmented.12 For example, it has been asserted by many authors that one reason for the fervor of Somalia's boundary agitation is the fact that it is an apparently cohesive state. Because of this, Sornal ia's irredentist policies do not risk opening a "Pandora's Box" of claims to external territory by other ethnic groups in the domestic scene. Similarly, it has also been sug- ges ted that Sornal i a coul d afford to annex territory wi thout worryi ng about upsetting whatever ethnic balance might be at work in the domestic political environment.13 Also, in a uni-ethnic state there would be little chance that cross-cutting, competing demands from other groups in society would offset and moderate the demands of any one group. Thus it has been maintained that Somali demands could be more clearly articulated than would have been the case if they were only one of many ethnic groups competing for the limited attention of the central gsvernmen t. There also seem to be situations in which the importance of ethnic criteria in the domestic political environment lead to boundary conflict. If an ethnic group has a particularly significant or pivotal place in the political environment, the 1 i kel ihood that its demands for some form of al- teration in the boundary status quo will result in the formulation of gov- ernment policy is greater. It nay well be that politically unimportant ethnic groups, or ethnic groups which operate in a political environment where ethnicity is not an important factor, have their demands ignored while those with greater political clout will be more successful in their claims. In this case, the presence of population overhang may be of initial importance, but the factor which is crucial in the generation of boundary conflict is the sal ience of ethnici ty in internal pol i tics. I Once again the Somali situation is cited as a case where this set of circumstances has led to boundary conflict. As was mentioned, while all citizens of the Somali Republic are of the same general ethnic unit, the Somali ethnic group is not a cohesive one. It is highly fragmented into kinship groups which compete, through party organizations, for pol i tical power and influence. In Somalia, then, ethnicity can be considered to be a sal ient pol i tical variable. An important explanatory force in Somalia's problems with Ethiopia, therefore, was the fact that the pol i tically impor- tant Daarood group was most strident in its agitation for the reunification of "Greater somalia".14 Because the Daarood depended heavily on grazing and water rights in Ethiopia, they frequently criticized the government for not taking active steps to reunite the Somali people-- and to thereby annex the Somali oc- cupied territory in Ethiopia which the Daarood depended upon so heavily. For example, in 1959 the Daarood deputies in the National Assembly vociferous- ly challenged Ethiopia's provocative "acts of aggression along the frontier," and demanded that the government take definite action on the Greater Somalia issue. 15 Such demands seem to have had considerable impact upon the tempo of the Somali Republic's claims to Ethiopian territory, and since the Daarood group was an integral element of the complex ethnic balance which then influenced Soma1 i politics, it is reasonable to surmise that it was the political salience of the affected ethnic group which accounted, at least partially, for the impact of its demands on Somali pol icy. A different type of hypothesis 1 inks general domestic unrest and the pressure of domestic problems to interstate conflict. Much as the specter of neo-colonial ism and continuing colonial ism were seen by some16 as an enemy against which the African states (no matter how strong their particular differences) could unite, the fomentation of boundary conflict could serve to create an external enemy to unify contentious elements of a population.~7 A boundary dispute could act as a safety valve for domestic turmoil by letting domestic groups which are at odds with one another vent their hostility against a real or imagined external enemy rather than against each other. The "safety valve" hypothesis seems to enjoy at least face validity for in those states plagued with domestic dissention the' inherent artificialicy of boundaries presents the government of the African state with an easily manipulated issue about which to rally support. Because the causes of domestic disruption may be diverse, the demands placed upon the government cannot all be presented as having their origin in the boundary issue area. Economic discontent, inter-ethnic friction, governmental inefficiency, etc., can each contribute to internal problems, but these factors may have little or nothing to do with the discontinuity between modern and traditional boundaries which was at the root of our previous set of hypotheses. No matter what the cause of the domestic turmoil, the central government has chosen to act within the boundary issue area, to foment boundary confl ict, as it seeks a solution for the turmoi 1. Given this situation, the observation that "any African state can have boundary problems if it wishes" assumes added significance and the ease with which boundary problems can apparently be fabricated works to the advantage of the state which wants to divert attention away from its internal problems. This tactic seems to have been adopted on several occasions. In 1963 Cahomey (now named Benin) began a boundary dispute with Niger. The conflict has been blamed upon the fact that there was a considerable amount of turmoil in Dahomey after the overthrow of President Maga, and it could be that the new ruler of Dahorney sought to foment boundary conflict with Niger in order to defuse this domestic dissent.'* Similarly, when the Somali National As- sembly was threatened with a no confidence vote in April 1962, it was rescued, at least partially, by an escalation in the tempo of the border conflict with Ethiopia.19 And again in 1964 when the general election in Somali was ap- proaching there was a serious outbreak of fighting with ~thio~ia.20 In the preceding cases the stimuli which elicited boundary conflict arose, di rectly or indirectly, from domestic actors within the states. There are also examples of boundary confl ict which do not seem related to domestic factors but rather seem to emanate from either the overall foreign pol icy stance of interacting states or from sources internal to the governing elite of a belligerant state itself. Several instances of conflict appear to indicate that if a pattern of generalized hostility exists between a group of states, the artificiality of African boundaries will make them convenient points for the articulation of that general hos ti 1 i ty.21 When African governments want to demonstrate, in a tangible and direct fashion, their displeasure with or hostility toward another state, boundary issues are ready made for such a purpose. In this case the forces which generate boundary conflict may arise out- side of the boundary issue area-- in the larger foreign policy environment of states-- but the policy which is formulated in response to such stimuli is clearly pursued within it. Domestic actors here are of peripheral impor- tance in the manifestation of boundary conflict, and while they may be affect- ed by the policy, or even cited as the cause of it, their substantive impact upon pol i cy formul ati on i s negl i gi bl e. The :!iger-Dahomey dispute has already been noted in support of the hypo- thesis which isolates domestic unrest as a primary factor in the outbreak of boundary cnnfl ict. But if the evidence is interpreted in another manner, this case can also support the hypothesis which places primary emphasis on general forei qn pol icy hosti 1 i ty as a cause of boundary confl i ct. After the overthrow of President Maga the new regime in Dahomey accused the Niger Republic of sup- porting a counterrevol utionary plot. In retal iation for this accusation, for the arrest of a number of its citizens by the Dahomians, and because Niger suspected Dahomey of aiding the subversive Sawaba Party, the Niger National Assembly announced that it would expel a1 1 Dahomians 1 iving on the northern side of the Niger River. Dahorney then closed its borders and effectively sealed landlocked Niger off from the outside world. This series of events signaled a dramatic downturn in the tone of foreign pol icy relationships between the two governments. In this context it is interesting to note that as diplomatic relationships soured, the long standing discus- sions on the status of Lete Island were transformed into rancorous debates. When the overall foreign policy position of the two states turned hostile, a previously dormant boundary issue flared up as well. It is also interesting that once relations improved the Lete Island issue lost importance and a corn- promise was quickly worked out. The Ghana-Upper Vol ta dispute of 1963-1966 was presented as a disagree- ment over an interpretation of evidence used in the definition of the border which separated the two countries. But the dispute seems to have had its origin in a more general friction between the states. From 1961 onward Ghana had attempted to forge close links with Upper Vol ta, but Nkrumah had been rebuffed in 1963. At the same time as it was turning away from Ghana, t'pper Volta had begun to pursue a rapprochement with the Ivory Coast. Nkrumah wac quite piqued at this policy shift by Upper Vol ta, and when Upper Vol ta began to suspect that Ghana was attempting to subvert its government, relationships between the two states reached a low ebb. It was at this juncture that the ongoing boundary discussions became an important means through which each country tried to influence the other. Ghana sought to demonstrate, through manipulation of the boundary issue, that i t could cause considerable trouble for an uncooperative neighbor, and Upper Vol ta attempted to damage Nkrumah's credibility by portraying his state as expansionist. Again, it appears that in this case boundary problems were simply a function of a more general and deep-seated pattern of antagoni sm between a set of states. Several othe examples could be given in support of this proposition (for example the Tanzania-Malawi dispute of 1967) but the major justification for its val idi ty is the observation that those states which have experienced little foreign policy conflict and which share a common ideological perspec- tive - Upper Volta and Niger, Chad and the Central African Empire, Mali and Aigeria - have had little or no boundary conflict.22 Another perspective attributes the origin of some boundary disputes to the governing elites of the various states. This perspective tends to down- grade the importance of both external infl uences and domestic factors. Rather, from this viewpoint, boundary disputes are explained by the perceptions, de- sires and motives of the governing elites in any country. Zartman suggests, for example, that the desire for status in the African comnunity could motivate leaders to embark upon an expansionist course.23 As evidence of this process he cites a remark by a Moroccan ambassador that his country needed more terri- tory "to look as big as Algeria". He further argues that one factor in Ghana's claims to Togolese territory was Nkrumah's continental aspi rations to status which were "far greater than the size of the country. "24 A similar view stresses the fact that changes in government leadership seem to be related to the outbreak of boundary conflict. It was pre- viously noted that boundary conflict fol lowed closely upon the heels of Maga's downfall in Dahomey. The same pattern can be discerned in the flareup of conflict between Sudan, Ethiopia and Chad after the 1964 revolution which overthrew the regime of General Abboud in Sudan. Boundary problems were dormant until the coup, but after the regime change they grew rapidly in intensity. Instability within a country's governing elite could potentially affect boundary issues in several ways. A regime change often marks a far reaching shift in the ideology, guiding assumptions and the norms of conduct for the unstable state. This could, in turn, reverse any pre-existing friendly relationships with neighboring states and facilitate the outbreak of boundary tensions. A1 so, since a regime change fosters suspicion, uncertainty and fears on the part of contiguous states about the intentions of the new leaders, the initial period after a coup could be a time of testing and probing the new regime through the fomentation of boundary troubles. Or finally, it could be that the newly installed elite in a country will foment boundary conflict as a means of generating popular support and solidifying their domestic position. This final explanation appears to be a modification of the "safety valve" hypothesis alluded to earlier. At this point it should be obvious that the "traditional wisdom" about the causes of boundary confl ict provides the analyst with a complex, confusing and often contradictory set of propositions from which to chose. Indeed, several different explanations are often given for the same case of conflict. Pl ausi ble explanations of the Soma1 i -Ethiopian dispute are offered by referring to the "safety val ve" hypothesis, the ethnic population overhang factor or the salience of ethnicity in domestic politics. How then are we to determine which of these propositions gives the most satisfactory general answer to the puzzles of boundary conflict? To adequately answer this question some means must be devised to subject each of these ideas to thorough and systeniatic empirical testing. We must compare each of the propositions to "real world" data and see which are con- firmed by the evidence and which do not stand the test of empirical analysis. This is necessary because at their present stage of development the insights presented in the various models represent little more that a set of ideas which previous analysts have gleaned from is01 ated inci dents of boundary con- flict and which further specify factors which might be at the root of such conflict. For the most part, moreover, these insights have been based upon case studies of boundary conflict and consequently we have little idea of their genera1 val i di ty. To ill ustrate, ethnic population overhang may indeed prove to be a significant factor in the generation of boundary conflict in the Horn of Africa, but such a conclusion will tell us little about the impact of ethnic overhang in the whole of Africa. To make a judgement about the universal validity of the postulated causes of conflict on a continent-wide scale, a multicase analysis must be conducted. We must look at the impact of such things as ethnic population overhang in as many cases as is possible before any definitive statement can be rendered. Thus if our knowledge about the factors which are related to boundary conflict is to move beyond conjecture, some means must be devised to subject our propositions to systematic mu1 ticase empi rical testing. As a first step i n that effort the propositions heretofore presented must be transformed into a group of formal hypotheses, the prerequisite of rigorous testing. 1. The greater the ethnic population overhang between a set of states. the greater the conflict between them. As was mentioned, this hypothesis enjoys the greatest support in the traditional 1 i terature. It posits that when an ethnic group is bisected by an artificial border there will be domestic disruption. This disruption will cause demands to be placed upon the central government of the state for redress of the situation, and these demands will elicit some form of boundary related foreign pol icy formulation. The aim of the foreign pol icy will be to force an adjustment of the border so that the disrupted ethnic group will limit its demands. If this proposition is sustained, some evidence will be provided to the effect that the African states have been directly affected by the legacy of colonial ism and owe much of their current conflict to the artificiality of thei r boundaries. 2. The greater the level of domestic ethnic fragmentation, the lower the level of boundarv conflict. This hypothesis begins to address the important relationship between domestic attributes and foreign policy behavior. It has been suggested that those states which suffer from excessi ve ethnic fragmentation cannot afford to engage in foreign policy activities, such as conflict over boundaries, which could be interpreted as being favorable to any single domestic ethnic group for fear of upsetting the domestic political equilibrium. Further, it has been suggested that ethnically fragmented states engage in irredentist activities only at the risk of opening a "Pandora's box" of subsequent claims to territory in neighboring states. Thus this hypothesis seeks to determine the extent to which a domestic attribute, ethnic fragmentation, acts to in- hibi t boundary conflict. 3. The greater the salience of ethnic criteria in domestic politics, the greater the levels of boundary conflict. This hypothesis, like the previous one, seeks to inject domestic variables into the analytic process. Integral to this statement is the idea that in a domes tic pol i tical environment where ethnic consi derations are of prime impor- tance the demands stemming from the presence of a superimposed border will have a greater impact upon policy than would have been the case if ethnic cri- teria were not important political variables. Whereas decision makers could perhaps afford to ignore the demands of an ethnic group if it was not pol i ti - cally important, this tactic would hinder political stability if a premium was placed upon ethnic identification in domestic politics. 4. The greater the degree of domestic instability, the greater the levels of boundary conflict. This is a formal expression of the "safety valve" hypothesis. In essence it posits that when domestic instability becomes a problem for a state's leaders those leaders will seek to divert attention from internal tensions by creating an external enemy to unify the population. In this case the widespread aware- ness of the artificial i ty of boundaries on the continent makes boundary issues particularly 1 i kely points for the creation of an external enemy. All leaders real i ze that thei r boundaries were created by a1 ien dip1 omats during the col oni a1 7eriod and share a certain ancunt of consensus about the conflict ooten- tial inherent in such a situation. Consequently, when they need an issue to manipulate boundary questions are particularly useful . 5. The greater the level of non-boundary foreign policy conflict for a state the greater the level of boundary conflict. This proposition seeks to test the val idi ty of those observations which postulate a linkage between the factors of general foreign policy and boundary disputes. It would seem only natural that ideologically hostile states would engage in conflictover boundaries and that there would be some spill-over from the more general domain of non-boundary issues to those of territorial concerns. Gi ven the eas i 1 y nanipul ated character of boundary quest ions, one might even presume that boundary conflict would be more intense than that found i n non- boundary areas. 6. The greater the disparity between size and desire for status, the greater the levels of boundary conflict. Thi s hypothesi s assumes that those states which have pretensions to high status in Africa but whose physical capabilities are not conmensurate with those pretensions will attempt to increase their size, and hence their capabilities, through expansionist activity. It could also be that a suc- cessful spate of boundary agitation will serve a symbolic function, i .e. , that it will demonstrate to others in Africa that a1 though a country may be small it still has the capability to influence others and is thus worthy of high status. 7. The qreater the level of elite instability, the greater the level of boundary conflict. This hypothesis posits a linkage between the elites in a state and its foreign pol icy. Di fferent analyst s have provi ded various expl anations about the manner in which turmoil at the elite level could lead to the development of boundary conflict. But in spite of this explanatory diversity, many agree that this linkage is an important one. Before attempting to deal directly with the problems posed by the need to empirically and systematically test these hypotheses, it is essential to isolate some of the basic patterns which are implicit in the statements. It appears that boundary conflict and the stimuli which are thought to moti- vate it could be 1 inked in two different ways. Several of the hypotheses suggest a direct 1 inkage between stimul i and pol icy, while others propose that the relationship is more indirect. In the group which suggestsa direct linkage, the presence of artificial boundaries serves as an immediate catalyst to conflictual policy. To develop this theme let us expand upon a few points made earlier. Superimposed boundaries create a discontinuity between the boundaries of the modern state and those of the traditional ethnic or ascription groups in a society. This discontinuity creates tension as the affected individuals are torn between the demands of their traditional groups and those of the modern state. These individuals will, as a consequence of that tension, issue demands on the central government to relieve either the discontinuity itself or the pressures which derive from it. When faced with a situation where significant elements of the polity are making demands for boundary adjustments, a government obviously has a plethora of means through which it can attempt to answer the demands, but three general options stand out. A government can try to lessen the popular pressure by relaxing the stringency of its control over the border, increasing its permeability, and thus easing the disruptive impact of the boundary. While this option is one solution to the problem, a number of factors would seem to blunt the viability of such a tactic. While the objective fact of independence may exist for the African states, the psychological realization of full independence may not yet have been achieved. As a consequence, governments of the black African states are generally quite jealous of the trappings of soverei gnty. The premi um pl aced upon symbol ic aspects of independence deri ves from the state's insecurity and lack of confidence in its genuine autonomy. Respect for the symbol i c aspects of soverei gnty thus serves to give evidence that these states are indeed fully independent, legitimate political enti ties. As control over its territory is one of the most overt manifestations of independence, it can be assumed that the first option, increasing the permeability of the border, will not be a very attractive policy gambit. The second option available to a state which is faced with domestic boundary demands is that of stifling dissent through coercion. Once again, this option may not appear to be particularly attractive. In a very real sense the 1 imi ted capa- bi 1 i ties of the African states to apply widespread sanctions will mi 1 i tate against this policy. While the military and police establishments of the various states often consume a disproportionate amount of total government expendi ture, these organizations are, in a-bsolute terms, of small size. A widespread campaign of coercive pressure could well overtax the military or police. This is particularly true when one realizes that to stifle boundary discontent and its consequent demands upon the government more than temporarily, the coercive measures would have to be implemented over a long period of time until new identification patterns had time I to form and replace the traditional ones. To be truly effective the appl ication of force could not be a one time affair, but rather would have to be a continuous fl process. African governments might also shy away from the coercive maintainance of boundaries due to the disruptive effect that such a policy could have on the domes- tic scene. It is a well established postulate of African politics that major threats to security for a regime are not external but rather emanate from the do- ~ mestic environment: It is not the country that is in danger of attack of conquest, but the government that is in danger of overthrow or collapse. Insecurity is thus endemic, inherent, and pol i tical rather than specific, external and mi 1 i tary.25 As a consequence, the use of domestic sanctions in response to demands miqht appear to be too dangerous a tactic if any other options remain since it could result in an escalation of dissent, aggravate an already disruptive situation and have the ef- fect of increasing discontent rather than ameliorating it. This action could thus pose a greater threat to the government's stability than the original problem. ~ In contrast to the two previous ploys, the third option which is open to the African leaders-- that of engaging in some form of foreign pol icy interaction with a neighboring state to alleviate the situation-- seems to have a number of positive advantages. This a1 ternative is relatively cheap to adopt. The spectrum of foreign policy activity is quite broad and ranges from verbal activity to actual physical contact. By confining policy action to verbal activity alone problems can be ad- L dressed without the allocation of funds or the use of scarce resources. Further, foreign policy activity has great symbolic value, and the awareness of a population L that the government is, through the medium of foreign policy, attempting to adjust a situation can serve to blunt the intensity of demands. This indirect satisfaction of demands can be effective whether or not any substantial a1 teration in the si tua- tion actually occurs. As long as the population believes that the government is at- tempting to look out for its interests the fervor of its demands, in the short run at least, may diminish. Thus for those hypotheses which posit a direct linkage between the presence of disrupti ve, superimposed boundaries and confl ict the pattern is clear. Boundaries cause disruption. This disruption leads to demands being made upon the government. And the government chases to respond to those demands through the medium of foreign nolicy conflict with a neighbor. As a consequence the hypotheses which fall within this general category include variables which are the product of the peculiar sort of boundaries which are found in Africa: ethnic population overhang, ethnic fragmen- tation and the salience of ethnic politics. Another set of statements specify a more indirect relationship between boundaries and policy. For this group conflict derives not so much from the specific imgact of boundaries upon the lives of individuals or the environment as from the impact that the boundary situation has had upon the perceptions and views of African decision makers. Boundaries in Africa are recogni zed by pol icy makers to be the creation of a1 ien diplomats, and the potential for disruption felt to be inherent in such a situation is also widely accepted. Thus the subjective awareness of the artificial character of Africa's boundaries is a major component of an African leader's view of continental affairs. Believing boundaries to be artificial, and aware of the disruption inherent in this situation, the African leaders see boundary issues as ones which are quite easily seized upon when conflict with other states can help in the pursuit of their individual, domestic or inter- national goals. Therefore when the African states need an issue to manipulate, for whatever reasons, the objecti ve fact of the existence of arti ficial , superimposed boundaries as well as the wide-spread subjective awareness of this situation make boundary questions a most likely focal point for the articulation of that issue. Within this category the relationship between boundaries and policy is obviously much less di- rect than was the case in the previous group since the stimuli which elicit foreign policy dctivity are not necessarily directly related to the presence of artificial boundaries. Hence the variables which are included in this group are such factors as el i te instability, domestic instability, non-boundary conflict and the size- status relationship. Hypothesis Testinq Mi th these comments in mind it is necessary to address the problems presented when attempting to test, in an empi rical manner, the previously elaborated hypothe- ses. The first step in a testing process requires that the variables in the hypo- thesis be operationalized; that is that they be transformed into a measurable form. For example, to assess the relationship between ethnic fragmentation and boundary conflict for a set of states it is necessary to develop a numerical index of the level of ethnic fragmentation within each country and to construct a similar index for the level of boundary conflict in each ca5e. Once this has been done it will be possible to correlate ethnic fragmentation with conflict and let the strencth of the observed relationship indicate the validity of that hypothesis which links the two variables. To this end the independent variables in the hypotheses were given numerical val ues by fol lowing we1 1 establ ished procedures for the construction of cornposi te measures of such variables .26 Briefly, several quantitative indicators were selected as potential measures for each independent variable. The statistical technique of factor analysis was then used to determine which of these potential i ndi ca tors appeared to be val id represen tati ves of each vari abl e, and then those which did demonstrate their relationship to the underlying independent variable were combined to give a composite numerical value for all variables in each African state.27 For example, the number of riots, the number of anti-government demonstrations and the number of deaths resul ting from domestic unrest were taken as indicators of domestic instability. By aggregating these values for each country, it was possible to develop a measure for that concept in all cases. The same process was repeated for each independent vari abl e in the hypotheses , and we were thus able to arrive at an expl ici t numerical value for each African state on each of the factors specified above.28 A different strategy had to be adopted in the operationalization of boundary conflict since foreign pol icy activity does not have any readily apparent quanti- tati ve indicators. Fortunately, an innovative form of data generation, events - data, has been developed which allows scholars to specify the vol ume and content of foreign policy interaction between a set of states. Students of African foreign policy are fortunate that one of the most elaborate and complete events data collections yet constructed, the AFRICA data file*, uses the black African countries as its sample group. With this data it was possible to categorize and measure the frequency of African boundary confl i ct .29 The AFRICA events data also gives us a more thorough inventory of boundary conflict than would have been the case if a more traditional technique had been adopted. Most analyses of boundary conflict isolate only the extreme, highly visable acts of overt physical or verbal conflict. However, it would seem that there is more to boundary conflict than just the spectacular event. We need to look at the routine event as we1 1 as the spectacular one-- the negative comment *Discussed in detail in the chapter by P. J. McGowan and T. H. Johnson in this book. as well as the armed clash-- and events data will tap more of these routine events. We thus have a more thorough and adequate representation of boundary confl ict with events data than would have otherwise been the case. Once the independent and dependent variables found in the hypotheses were o~erationalized the relationships in them could be empi rically tested using simple bi -variate correlation. Correlation analysis indicates the degree to which a pair of variables in an hypothesis co-vary. That is, it shows the degree to which a rise in for example, ethnic fragmentation, is accompanied by a rise in boundary conflict. If the correlation coefficient (which ranges fro^ +1.00 to -1.00) is larger than +.30 or -.30, a relationship of moderate strength is indicated and our confidence in the validity of the hypothesis is increased. It is also important to note the direction of the correlation which is indicated by the sign of the coefficient. If we have a moderate-to- strong positive relationship (+.30 to +1.00) it means that a rise in the level of the independent variable is accompanied by a rise in the level of the depen- dent one. Conversely, a moderate-to-strong negative relationship (-.30 to -1.00) indicates that a rise in the level of the independent variable is associated with a fall in the level of the dependent variable. The results of the hypothesis testing process are presented in Table 1. TABLE 1 CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS I nde~enden Dependent Hypothesis Correlation Variable (A) Variable (B) Category (A) with (B) Ethnic Population Boundary Di rec t +. 07 Overhang Conflict Ethnic Boundary Di rec t +.I6 Fragmentation Conflict Domestic Boundary Indi rect - .38 Instability Conflict Non- boundary Boundary Indirect +.08 Conflict Conflict Si ze-Status Boundary Indi rect -. 38 Relationship Conflict El i te Boundary Indi rect +.54 Instabi 1 i ty Conflict Salience of Boundary Di rect +.31 Ethnic Politics Conflict The results indicate that four cf the seven hypotheses could be verified at moderate levels of confidence.30 Domestic instability, the size-status relationship, elite instability and the sdience of ethnic politics all seem to have a relationship to boundary conflict. The remainins variables, while mentioned in the traditional literature on boundary conflict, do not show much relationship to confl ict when eval uated in an empirical , systematic, mu1 ti-case manner. The strength of the relationship between conflict and the salience of ethnic politics indicates that there is a slight tendency for states that have politically important domestic ethnic groups to engage in boundary conflict. This would seem compatible with an intuitive assessment of the dynamics of boundary conflict since it is reasonable to expect that a state whose domestic environment places a premium on ethnicity would be more likely to respcnd to demands issued by such a group. Moreover, the relative weakness of this correlation is not surprising, for while there may be a number of African states where ethnicity is an important political factor, it is not likely that there are many in which an ethnic group is both politically important and directly affected by boundary disruption. Were we to confine the analysis to those states where key ethnic groups are bisected by a national border, such as Somalia or Togo, the strength of the relationship would probably be much greater. In this regard it is interesting to note the lack of correlation between population overhang and conflict. It appears that it is not the specific rmgnitude of ethnic population overhang which is the causal factor in the generation of boundary conflict, but rather the crucial variable seems to be whether the demands of the affected group are deemed to be politically salient. This is an important point which seems to have been missed by many previous analysts of boundary confl ict. Our analysis also indicates that there is a moderate correlation between the size and status of an African state and its propensity to engage in boundary conflict. While the magnitude of the correlation signals a moderately strong relationship between the t.wo factors, the di recti on of the correlation (negative) imp1 ies that cur original hypothesis-- which posited that the high-status, small-side states wtiuld be prone to engage i n boundary conflict-- is in Error. Insi,ead, it appears that large stztes which have little status in the African comnunity are more likely to fomen: bocndary conflict. A more va1 id proposi ;;ion lirking the t.wo variables would thus read: "Large states with little status in Africa are-more 1 i kely to engage in boundary conflict. " It could be that those large African states which are given little status by their fellow states on the continent seek to increase their status by initiating expansionist policy. Such policy might be calculated to demon- strate the power of the large state and to convince other African nations that it deserves greater recognition in African affairs. In any case, while this finding contradicts the traditional 1 i terature on African boundary confl ict, it is consistent with at least one other investigation of the impact of size and status on state behavior. Maurice East has found that large, underdeveloped (and hence low status) nations tend to engage in more general foreign policy conflict than any other type of state.31 Thus, the African states differ little from others in the international system in this regard. The strongest of the correlations was between elite instability and boundary conflict. A number of possible explanations for this phenomena were offered earlier in this chapter. The question then arises, which of the possible explanations are the most viable? Changes in African 1 eadershi p are often accompanied by an a1 teration in the prevail ing ideologies, atti tudes and views of the decision making elites in the unstable states. We have mentioned that such an alteration in the status quo could lead to a reversal in any pre-existing climate of foreign policy amity. However, there seems to be one major flaw in this explanation. It may well be that elite changes transform peaceful relationships into confl ictual ones, but would elite instabil i ty not a1 so transform confl ictual relationships into peaceful ones? In the long run it would seem that such changes in the tone of foreign policy caused by elite instability would cancel each other out and the strength of the correlation would diminish accordingly. The two remaining explanations therefore seem more plausible. Turmoi 1 at the hi ghest levels of government reduces the predictabil i ty of an unstable state's foreign pol icy. When an established elite is removed from power, by whatever means, those states which have been interacting with the outgoing el i tes are no longer dealing with a knownquanti ty whose probable reaction to any pol icy initiative can be gauged with accuracy. A need may thus arise for tes ti ng and probi ng the newly establ i shed government i n order to di scern their mode of operation and to determine the 1 imi ts of acceptable foreign pol icy action. Neighboring countries may therefore seize upon such an opportunity to foment boundary confl ict, an issue which is quit? at:ienabl e to manipulation when the exigencies of the times demand, in order to test the new elites. It is also possible to postulate that the "safety vahe" hypothesis has some relevance for elite instability as well as for general social unrest. As elites change, new leaders could seek to secure the support of their popu- lation by creating an external enemy with the manipulation of boundary issues. A good deal of credence is lent to this explanation by the fact that the hypothesis 1 inking domestic turmoil and conflict was also confirmed by the data analysis. If leaders of a state have used the fomentation of boundary issues to offset one form of instability, it is quite likely that the same strategy would be used by elites in an attempt to secure their position of power. The convergence of these two veri f i ed hypothese s seems to prov' je added empirical support to the safety valve proposition in both situations. Before attempting to draw some general conclusions from the analysis, it is important to consider the hypotheses which were not verified. The lack of support for the ethnic population overhang hypothesis has already been cited, but how could it be that an apparently invalid hypothesis could generate enough support to become almost axiomatic in the literature as an explanation for conflict? Of course there are a multitude of possible explanations for this, but the most straightforward one involves a comparison of the data base in this study with those of previous analysts. Whereas the present work has attempted to base its conclusions on a thorough and systematic analysis of the 32 black African states, most previous studies have been idiographic in nature; that is, they have formed conclusions on the analysis of a single case of boundary conflict. When a single case forms the sole base for analysis it is often possible that factors unique to that case are accorded general validity. This seems to be a particularly acute problem in the ethnic population overhang example since previous works have not only been based upon a single case, but the majority of them have also been based upon the same case, that of the relations between Somalia, Kenya and Ethiopia in the Horn of Africa. It is this particular case where ethnic population overhang, by the Soma1 i people, appears to have had the most im- mediate impact upon policy. Therefore these studies have tended to reify the importance of population overhang and this factor has been accorded almst universal validity. It is also interesting to note that conflict in the general sense has 1 i ttle relationship to boundary conflict. It is almost intuitively obvious that if states engage in general foreign policy conflict they will also tend to conflict over boundaries, but again this does not seem to be the case. Perhaps such a finding indicates that African leaders make an irnplici t or expl ici t distinction between boundary confl ict and other types of foreign pol icy conflict. Besides providing additional justification for an investi- gation of boundary confl ict, this a1 so seems to partial ly veri fy our contention that the politics of boundaries occupies an important and unique place in the cognitive and operational milieux of African leaders. It also indicates that when conflict over boundaries is fomented, such action is designed to further very special needs and goals of the state. We now have a rather comprehensive inventory of the factors which serve as specific catalysts for boundary conflict, and we have also been able to discard some of the variables which have incorrectly been surmised to cause conflict. We can say, with some confidence, that elite instability, general domestic turmoil, the salience of ethnicity in domestic politics and the desire for status by large states are determinants of boundary confl ict. Conversely, ethnic population overhang, ethnic fragmentation and non-boundary conflict have 1 i ttle relationship to boundary tensions. But what larger generalizations are possible from these results? What overall patterns are discernable in the data? It is possible to make a tentative judgement about the relative potencies of internal and external sources of boundary pol icy. At independence i t was widely assumed that domestic factors would be of paramount importance to African leaders as they formulated foreign pol icy. In the immediate post-independence era i t was fel t that the rnos t pressi ng problems for the African states would 1 ie in the areas of domestic consol idation, national integration, institution building and the like. As a consequence, when foreign policy was initiated, it would be designed to support and further these pressing domestic goals and pri ori ties: The determi nants of foreign pol icy in the new African states are often obscured because the di sti nction between foreign and domestic policy is often difficult to establish. Activities and decisions which on the surface fa1 1 within the realm of foreign policy may well be designed as much or more for internal consumption as for their effect on relations with other states.32 The personalization of African pol itics was also thought to reinforce the salience of domestic factors in foreign policy formulation. As the African states moved toward one-party government, decision making authority for both domestic and international questions became centralized in the hands of a single leader or a small coterie of his followers. These leaders had a primary concern with securing their positions of power within the state, and foreign pol icy thus was more likely to be a reflection of that domestic concern. Similarly, the lack of bureaucratization within the foreign pol icy establishments of the new African states was felt to increase the salience of domestic factors. The lack of a well developed foreign policy bureaucracy made the gathering of accurate information about the external environment difficult to accomplish. With no clear view of the external situation those factors which could be more easily gauged-- domestic forces-- assumed 5-eater importance. While such arguments seem compel1 ing, not all analysts shared these conclusions, and some concluded that external factors were of equal if not greater importance in determinina the content of African forei gn no1 icy. Zartman succinctly surrmarizes this viewpoint in the following statement: A1 though there may be some relation between domestic and foreign politics, there is frequently too little relation between domstic and foreign policies. Western African relations are anything but "domestic pol icy pursued by other means ... carried out beyond the boundaries of the state ...." For the most part, intra-African foreign policy has little to do with domestic needs or purposes. Instead, it is often an exercise in pure politics-- a struggle for external in- fluence for its own sake ... .33 Thus this author would seem to discount the 1 inkage between domestic factors and foreign policy. Instead, he stresses the leader's desire for power in the international environment as a motivating force. Fortunately, our research sheds some light upon this controversy and, for boundary pol i tics at least, indicates that internal factors do indeed exhibit the greatest correlation with foreign policy. While only one of the three hypotheses which incl ude external variables coul d be confi rmed, three of the four remaining internal factors produced significant correlations. We can thus affirm the accuracy of those who have isolated domestic factors as crucial in the generation of foreign policy activity. Perhaps the most significant general conclusion to be drawn from the data analysis concerns the nature of the relationship between the colonial heritage and con temporary probl ems. Recall that the various hypotheses were di chotorni zed into direct and indirect groupings. Hypotheses in the direct category represented immediate 1 i nkages between the arti ficial i ty of African boundaries and contemoorary confl ict. If the nany previous assumptions about the magnitude of colonialism's impact upon the foreign and domestic policies of the African states are to be sustained, one would expect that the majority of valid hypo- theses about the correlates of boundary conflict would fall within this group. To sustain the proposition that colonial actions are at the root of current problems, it must be demonstrated that an artifact of colonialism (like arti- ficial boundaries) served as a specific catalyst to modern intra-African con- fl ict. Because the direct hypotheses represent this immediate 1 inkage between boundary conf 1 ict and artificial boundaries-- because the variables speci fied in the direct hypotheses impel the various African states to act-- it is these propositions which must be confirmed to validate the suspected link between colonialism and modern problems. Among the original hypotheses there is a rather even split between the two categories (four hypotheses in the indirect group and three in the direct) but three of the four verified statements fell within the indirect group. Such a finding seems to indicate that rather than being compelled to engage in boundary conflict by the endemic disruption of boundary artificiality, African leaders tend to manipulate the potentiality for confl ict latent in the boundary situation when the exigencies of the times demand. If faced with elite instabi 1 i ty, domestic turmoi 1 or a perceived need to increase thei r status, the African leaders seize upon boundary questions as a means of attempting to improve their various positions. Further, it is possible to conclude from this that the impact of colonial ism on the modern African scene is more indirect that heretofore suspected. In the case of boundary problems and conflict the impact of the colonial legacy has not compelled the states of Africa to fight, but rather it has created a situation in which the African leaders can exercise a wider latitude of policy choice than would have been the case if the continent's boundaries were of a more natural configuration. In all probability boundary disputes and the politics of boundaries will continue to be an important aspect of intra-African foreign pol icy activity. If past patterns hold up, boundary problems may be an outgrowth of domestic turmoil as the decision makers attempt to create a set of external enemies against which to rally the ~opulation. In a similar manner, when elites in a country become unstable, when rulers have reason to suspect that their tenure in power is threatened, boundary troubles could follow as those leaders seize upon the ever present boundary situation as a means of generat- ing support for their leadership. It is also probable that if politically important ethnic groups demand a boundary adjustment, foreign pol icy confl ict will be the result. And finally, it is quite likely that large states which feel that they are not accorded sufficient status in the African community will attempt to use boundary issues as a means of demonstrating their capa- bilities in hopes that such action will convince other states that they are worthy of greater consideration in continental affairs. In a more general vein, it is likely that domestic factors will continue to have primacy in this facet of African foreign policy. Perhaps as the foreign pol icy bureaucracies of the states become more entrenched and sophisticated, or if African pol i tics should become less personalized, external factors will come to exert a greater influence on the formulation of pol icy. And finally, while the impact of the colonial past on contemporary Africa cannot be denied, the immediacy of the linkage between the past and the present problems of foreign relations is likely to be less apparent than some analysts would have us believe. If boundary politics are in any way typical of the full range of African foreign policy behavior, the colonial legacy will not cause modern conflict as much as it will provide a rationale, or perhaps an excuse, for action when the situation demands. END NOTES 1 Harold Sprout and Margaret Sprout, "Environmental Factors in the Study of International Relations," in James N. Rosenau, ed., International Politics and Foreign Policy (New York: Free Press, 1966), p. 43. 2 Joseph C. Anene, The International Boundaries of Nigeria (London: Long- mans, 1970), p. 3. 3 Rupert Emerson, "Nation Building in Africa," in Karl Deutsch and William J. Fol tz, eds., Nation Building (New York: Atherton Press, 1963), p. 105. 4 I. William Zartman, "The Foreign and Military Politics of African Boundary Problems," in C. G. Widstrand, ed., African Boundary Problems (Upsal la: Scandinavian Insti tute of African Studies, 1969), p. 79. 5 2.. Pounds, Pol i tical Geography (New York, 1963), pp. 61 -65. 6 Ravi Kapil , "On the Confl ict Potential of Inherited Boundaries in Africa," World Politics 18 (1966): 656. 7 Zartman, "Politics," p. 82; Kapil, "Conflict Potential," pp. 665-666; R. Mansell Prothero," North East Africa: A Pattern of Conflict." in R. M. Prothero, ed., Geography of Africa (New York: Praeger, 1969), p. 201; and Saadia Touval, "The Sources of Status Quo and Irredentist Pol icies ," in Widstrand, ed., Boundary Problems, pp. 11 5-1 16. 8 Zartman, "Politics," p. 82. 9 Adekunle Ajala, Pan Africanism (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1974). 10 Prothero, "Pattern of Conflict," p. 157. 11 Touval, "Status Quo," p. 117. 12 Kapi 1, "Conflict Potential ," pp. 672-673 and Touval , "Status Quo," p. 109. 13 Not all analysts accept this contention. Indeed many deny that Somalia is a cohesive state. While a1 1 of its citizens are Somal is, and while the government does justify its irredentist claims by saying that it wishes to unite all Somalis, close observers have noted that there are several kinship groups in the Somal i Republic which function as competing and conflicting ethnic groups. As shall be seen in the next few pages, these analysts explain 1 Soma1 ia's pol icy on the basis of domestic ethnic political competition. See, I for example, A. A. Castagano, "The Soma1 i-Kenyan Controversy: Implications for the Future," Journal of Modern African Studies 2 (1964): 165-188. 1 14 Ibid., p. 165. I 15 Ibid. 16 Kwame Nkrumah, Neo-Colonialism (New York: International Publishers, 1965). Touval, "Status QUO," p. 116; Castagano, "Controversy," p. 533; and Zartman, "Pol itics ," p. 87. Touval, "Status Quo," p. 117. Castagano, "Controversy," p. 534. Touval, "Status Quo," p. 117. A. Alliott, "Boundaries and Law in Africa," in Widstrand, ed., Boundary Problems, p. 19.; Touval, "Status Quo," p. 113; and Zartman, "Politics," p. 88. Zartrnan, "Politics," p. 88. Ibid, p. 87. Ibid. I. William Zartman, International Relations in the New Africa (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1966), p. 49. The two-step factor analysis method was used to demonstrate the convergent and discriminant val idi of the indicators for each variable. See Dona1 d T. Campbell and Donald W. Fiske, "Convergent and Discriminant Validation by the ilul tiTrai t-Mu1 tiMethod Matrix," Psychological Bul letin 56 (March 1959), for a discussion of this approach. See Patrick McGowan and R. Lewis, "Cul ture and Foreign Pol icy Behavior in Black Africa ," (Paper presented at the American Pol i tical Science Association Annual Meeting, 1973). for an application of this technique. And see J. Barron Boyd, Jr., "The Deter- minants of Boundary Related Foreign Pol icy in Africa," (Unpubl ished PhD Dissertation, University of South Carolina, 1975), for a complete discus- sion of the methodology used in this particular operationalization process. For a comprehensible discussion of factor analysis, see R.J. Rummel, "Un- derstanding Factor Analysis," Journal of Conflict Resolution (1967). Data for the operational i zation of the variables domestic instabi 1 i ty, ethnic fragmentation, the sal ience of ethnic pol itics and elite instabil- i ty was selected from Donald G. Morrison, ~t.. . , Black Africa: A Com- parati ve Handbook (New York: Free Press, 1972). The specific indicators for these variables are as follows: Domestic Instability; Communal i ns tabi 1 i ty Turmoi 1 Intensi ty of violence Ethnic Fragmentation; Largest ethnic unit as a 7; of total population Principles of reckoning descent Settlement patterns Hierarchy above fami ly Type of authori ty sys tern Sal ience of Ethnic Pol i tics; Number of political parties Legislative fractionalization Percentage vote cast for winning party in pre- independence election. Elite Instability; Cabinet resignations and dismissals Elite instability. Idon-boundary conflict was measured through a factor analysis of Patrick McGowants AFRICA events data project. The entire data set was factor analyzed and those events which appeared on a conflict factor were com- bined to form the final index. Ethnic population overhang was measured by a close analysis of the ethnic patterns tables for contiquous coun- tries found in the Black Africa ~ahdbook. Evidence of ethnic popula- tion overhang was noted and the number of individuals on either side of the border was recorded. The population figures for groups transcending state borders were transformed into a total population overlap index with the fol 1 owing formul a : where POI= population overhang index El= the larger ethnic unit ES= the smaller ethnic unit N= the total number ethnic units bisected by the border. Status was measured by computing the ratio of foreign policy events sent to those received by a state. This method of measuring status is based upon a communications model and assumes that those states with greater status will tend to receive more comnunications, through the medium of foreign pol icy, than they send. See Steven J. Brams, "The Structure of Infl uence Re1 ationships in the International System," in James N. Rosenau, ed. , International Politics and Foreiqn Pol icy (New York: Free Press, 1069), pp. 583-599. Once status was measured, it was a rather simple matter to construct a size to status ratio figure for each state. These independent variables were intercorrelated, and no evi dence of mu1 ti- col ineari ty was observed. 29 A composite index for boundary conflict in each case was constructed by factor analyzing the boundary conflict data in the AFRICA file. Those acts which appeared on a conflict dimension were used in the computation of a boundary conflict index for each state. 30 The analysis is based upon the 22 black African states which had some form of boundary conflict during the 1964-1961 period. 31 Maurice East, "Size and Foreign Policy Behavior," World Politics 25 (1974): 556-576. 32 L. Gray Cowan, "Political Determinants," in Vernon McKay, ed., African Diplomacy (New York: Praeger, 1966), p. 120. 33 Zartman, International Relations, p. 53. THE AF9ICA PROJECT AND THE COMPARATIVE STUDY OF AFRICAN FOREIGN POLICY Patrick J. McGowan, University of Southern California Thomas H. Johnson, Uni versi ty of Southern Cal i fornia In this chapter we wish to describe the methods and some findings of the African Foreign Relations and International Conflict Analysis (AFRICA) Project as they relate to the comparative study of African foreign policy. Because the AFRICA project uses a research strategy based on recent advances in research methods for the comparati ve description and explanation of forei gn policy behavior, it is important to discuss briefly a number of the assumptions and technical aspects of our approach before we review the contributicqs of this project to our understanding of African international relations. Method01 ogi cal and Conceptual Concerns Among the major objectives of the discipline of international relations (IR) are the description, explanation and evaluation of the behavior of international and transnational actors within the mu1 tidimensional inter- national system. Unl i ke many physicists and chemists in their laboratories, the international relations scholar cannot observe first-hand or experimental- ly manipulate most of the more intriguing and important events that occur in the world. In addi tion, international phenomena are highly dynami c--process and change are the essence of IR. The analyst of international relations is therefore confronted with a dilemma of considerable magnitude - how do we --- know what we claim to know about the behavior of international actors such as -------- - -- African states? How one answers this question, we would argue, has a great impact on one's preferred research strategy for creating knowledge and the uses one is will ing to make of the knowledge once it is created. A common response to this dilemma made by many students of worl d pol i tics is based on the notion that international phenomena are non-repeatable and unique and must be treated as such. If an analyst adopts this belief, he will likely choose to describe and explain a particular aspect of international relations by undertaking a detailed case stuay that attempts to exhaust every relevant facet of the problem at hand. The knowledge produced by such case studies is often ideographic, that is, knowledge of the particular and the unique. Thus case studies can provide very rich descriptions of selected events but they often fail to produce knowledge that is rep; icable, veri- fiable and general. Without general, or -- nomothetic knowledge, it is dif- ficul t and perhaps impossible to explain and eval ~ate behavior. l This is so because every explanation makes reference to generalizations. To "explain" the death of a relative, for example, one may say that the deceased died from a heart attack. The specific and unique event of one person's death is "explained" by reference to our general knowledge that when the normal functioning of the human heart is interrupted, death general ly follows. In a similar fashion, we may explain conflict between Somalia and Ethiopia by showing how it is a particular instance of a general pattern of border disputes that occur frequently in Africa because of the arbitrary nature of most African boundaries. Hence, while we do think that case studies of the foreign pol icies of particular African states are descriptively useful2, we have chosen a research strategy that we feel is a more direct route to general knowledge about African international behavior. The AFRICA Project i s based upon the assumption that international phenomena are repeatable and not necessarily unique. If they are filtered through useful conceptual categories , these phenomena can be grouped and analyzed in a systematic fashion. Among the highly repeatable aspects of African foreign policy are voting at the United Nations, visits among heads of state and government, the receipt of foreign economic and mil i tary assistance, border confl i cts and denunciations of South African apartheid. Moreover, while each vote, visit, aid contract, border closure and verbal condemnation are unique in that they happen only once at a specific time and place, they - can also be conceived of as types of foreign policy behavior. To do so, one must have a useful typology of categories of action exchanged between states and other international and transnational actors that permits the cl assi fi cation of each action as to its type. Once classified and coded, the particular, unique foreign policy action retains these characteristics but it also acquires new attributes for it has been expl ici characteri zed as representing a certain type of forei gn pol icy behavior. These types may be compared along a variety of dimensions such as their origin, their targets, their frequency over time, their relations to other types of behavior, their "causes" and "consequences" and thei r eval uati ve imp1 i cations for the acting state and its regional international system. Thus, the AFRICA project has adopted a "scientific" approach in its research because we assume that African foreign policy behavior is repeatable and not necessarily unique and because we want to create nomothetic knowledge about this behavior that is reliable, valid and general. This approach is necessary if we are to claim to be able to explain why African leaders be- have the way they do in the international arena.3 Moreover, the type of knowledge produced by the AFRICA project is essential for an understanding of where particular African states, as described in ideographic case studies, fit into the more general patterns of African international behavior. As a research strategy the scientific approach has many varied appli- cations. Physicists, geologists, medical researchers and international re- lationists use a wide variety of different techniques, yet we would argue that a1 1 scientific research is characterized by explicit conceptualization, careful measurement usually leading to the quantification of data and .he com- parison of as many cases as possible and appropriate. These features of the scientific approach have the consequence of creating what has been called "intersubjectively communicable knowledge" because the methods and findings are created and reported in such a fashion as to make them relatively inde- pendent of the personal val ues and i deol ogi es of the researcher .4 Findings can be shown to be independent of their originator's values by repl ication wherein other researchers with presumably different values are able to repeat or perhaps modify the original knowledge base. For repl ication to occur the original data must be available to other researchers. The AFRICA project data are available to readers of this chapter for research uses or for the purpose of replicating any of the findings we shall subsequently report.5 in the remainder of this section we shall focus on the issues of comparison, data- making and measurement, and conceptualization. The Cases-for-Comparison The central idea in comparative analysis is to make inferences about the truth of hypotheses using several instances of the phenomenon in question. For example, if a student is interested in explaining the dependency on France of its former African colonies, he would examine relations between France and all these territories rather than merely studying the foreign pol icy of a single former French territory. By identifying similarities and differences in France's relations with a large number of African states the analysis moves beyond a particular case to higher levels of generalization. Because our research seeks to produce general knowledge about the sources, types and consequences of African foreign relations, the AFRICA project created a large-scale, quantitative and comparable data set. Thirty-two independent states of sub-Saharan black Africa (as listed on Table 3) or thei r forty- three pol i ti cal regimes between January 1 , 1964, and December 31, 1966, represent our cases-for-comparison. These states and regimes were selected for a number of reasons. First, the states represent a cluster of countries that for various reasons (e.g., newness of statehood, lack of appropriate data, Western ethnocentrism, etc.) have been to a large extent neglected i n previous comparati ve research concerning foreign pol icy behavior .6 Second, these states represent a re1 ati vely homogeneous subset of African states, excluding the quite different white minority controlled territories of Southern Africa and the North African Arab-speaking states that previous research had shown to be rather distinct in their international behavior.7 Third, these states are identical to the countries included in the North- western and York Universities African National Integration Project which has gathered a very extensive data set on historical and domestic characteristics of each state of black ~fri This is especial ly advantageous considering the special interest of the AFRICA project in examining the relationships between domestic factors such as political regime change or modernization and the external behavior of these states.9 Let us be clear what these cases represent. In talking about African foreign policy behavior one may be thinking about the foreign relations of African states. If that is the case, then with our AFRICA project data one may look at the behavior of the thirty-two states during the three year period 1964-66. Upon occasion, however, when we talk about this topic we mean the foreign pol i cies of certain governments or pol i ti cal regimes. Thus, between the beginning of 1964 and the end of 1966 the state of Ghana had two different governments, that of President Kwame Nkrumah and then a mi 1 i tary-based gov- ernment that took power in an anti-Nkrumah coup d'etat on February 23, 1966. This fact creates "two" Ghanas and it may well be that the foreign policies of these two quite different regimes were different as well. Hence, if one is thinking of the foreign policy behavior of governments, the AFRICA data are also organized in a fashion to permi t comparisons among the forty-three di fferent regimes that governed these thi rty-two states between 1964 and 1966. The time period selected, 1964-66, was chosen because it represents the first period of political unrest for these thirty-two African countries after receiving independence.10 During this period, military-ledccupsd'etat rep1 aced ci vi 1 ian rulers with mi 1 i tary-bureaucrati c governments in one-quarter of these countries. This instability in some but not all states in this one region and during this short expanse of time provides an ideal focal point for an inquiry into the relationships between political regime change and foreign pol icy behavior. This time period is also advantageous because it enables the researcher to evaluate the effect of the initial stages of nation-building in most of these countries. Twenty-two of these states had been independent less than four years by 1964. Therefore, special attention can be given to the analysis of political development in its earliest stages and its possible effect on the foreign policies of African states. Conceptual ization, Data-making, and Measurement Given the AFRICA project's decision to study the foreign pol icy behavior of thi rty-two bl ack Afri can countries and thei r forty-three regimes we turned to "events data" for comparable indicators of external behavior. Events data, which were developed by Dr. Charles A. McClelland and associates at the University of Southern ~al refer to verbal and physical actions that international actors direct toward their external environments.12 Put simply, events data serve as an indicator of a state's behavior by recording "who says or does what to whom." Thus, events data are historical materials and, actually, very "traditional . " The main difference between the tradi- tional, case-study scholar and the quantitative analyst of foreign pol icy is that the latter is dealing with historical events in terms of quantity and at a higher level of abstraction while the case study analyst focuses on individual or small groups of narrative, historical accounts. 13 The rapid growth of events data as a research technique can be attributed to the re- di scovery that the study of international relations is largely an historical subject and the availability and utility of electronic computers for the storage, retrieval and analysis of such data.14 Our use of events data makes our basic unit-of-analysis the foreign policy acts that are exchanged among African states and governments. Be- tween any three African states, for example, there are six possible linkages: For the thi rty-two black African states there are 992 possible intra-African "dyadic" linkages. l5 This means that in order to understand black African i ntra-state behavior the researcher must look beyond the conventional view of thirty-two states and concentrate on the conception of relational flows or action among African states. The notion of relational flows counters the idea that a state has a single, uni-dimensional , foreign pol icy. Instead states or regimes have many different foreign pol icies that are constantly shifting and changing according to a wide variety of factors.16 One variable that plays a central role in this repertory of behavior and action is the target of a foreign policy action. The AFRICA project defines foreign pol icy actions or events as "the official, nonroutine, deli berate, overt actions of governmental representatives, directed at external actors for the express political purpose of modifying the behavior of those targetsU.l7 The target of the action will influence the action itself. For example, Nkrumah's Ghana did not act the same way towards the Soviet Union and the Ivory Coast. Not only did the target, be it the U.S.S.R. or the Ivory Coast, evoke variation in Ghana's foreign policy, but actions also vary according to "issue areas. "18 Put simply, different kinds of subject matters lead to different types of action and reaction on the part of the nations involved. Hence, each African state has mu1 tiple foreign policies that cannot be viewed in a static way but rather as a flow of behavior that changes direction and speed according to many variables. To operational ize this conception of foreign pol icy acts, the AFRICA project relied on McClelland's notion that international interactions are "single action i tems of a nonroutine, extraordinary, or newsworthy character that in some clear sense are directed across a national boundary and have, in most instances, a specific target."19 Three points are worth mentioning concerning this idea that directly infl uenced our data col lection process. First, the assumption that action is of a "newsworthy character" led the AFRICA project to search for a news source that could serve as a reliable basis for the identification and abstraction of African foreign pol icy acts. The Africa Research Bull etin (Pol i ti cal and Economic Series) was selected to fulfil 1 this purpose. This single source was chosen not only on the basis of "face validity," that is, it has the reputation among African area special- ists as being the most comprehensive and accurate chronology of African political and economic affairs currently available, but also because it is a regional ly specialized source. Africa Research Bulletin was viewed as much more appropriate for our research purposes than a world-wide data source such as the New York Times because research has shown such sources to report little African behavior. 20 The second assumption concerning McClel land's notion of international interactions that directly infl uenced the AFRICA project's data gatherGng operations dealt with the idea that the interactions were "single action i terns. " The AFRICA project foll owed this notion by operational ly defini ng a foreign pol icy act as "a simple declarative sentence about an activity undertaken by a state or its official representative(s), wherein it may be inferred that the actor undertook the action in order to affect the behavior of the external recipient of the act."21 By concentrating on simple declara- tive sentences, the AFRICA project operationally employed a 1 inguistic unit of analysis which represents the most di screte uni t conveying information about forei gn pol icy behavior.22 The last point to be noted about this conceptual definition is that it conceives of foreign pol icy behavior as being carried out by means of both discrete verbal and physical (non-verbal) control attempts by an actor directed at a target.23 A1 though the distinctions are often ambiguous, concrete differences can be seen between verbal and physical acts. For example, most threats in international relations are usually conceived of as verbal acts with contingent intent directed from one actor to another, but tacit threats are also possible. Physical acts, such as border closures or troop movement, often signal threats by non-verbal communication. In fact, if we are to understand foreign pol icy behavior in a thorough, complete fashion, we should attempt to observe regularities in the relationships between the use of verbal and physical means in undertaking foreign pol icy. The AFRICA project utilized three separate stages in the collection and management of its foreign pol icy data. The first state of the process involved the identification and abstraction of individual events from the text of Africa Research Bulletin. After identifying behavior that satisfied our codebook's definition of a foreign policy act, a trained abstractor then translated the act onto a code sheet in the subject-verb-object form of a simple declarative sentence, such as "Guinea signed a trade agreement with Hungary". Once the act was identified and abstracted, the second stage of the data-making process took place. This phase of the procedure dealt with the numerical coding of the previously abstracted event across thirty subs tanti ve variables and nine "bookkeeping" type codes used by the AFRICA project.24 The number of variables coded is much more substantial than similar data sets. The WE IS^^ project, for example, coded only five variables: date, actor, action, target and arena. It was felt that the wide variety of variables that were coded for each event would enable a researcher to examine comparatively a wide variety of questions associated with foreign pol icy behavior. The last stage of the data-making process dealt with the storage and management of the data. To effectively handle a data set of this size it was vital to utilize an electronic computer. Before this was done, however, the data had to be made "machine readable." Hence, each of the 14,669 coded foreign policy actions had to be keypunched on computer cards so that they could be read, stored and retrieved by the computer. Following our rules, the event "After the overthrow of President Nkrumah, Ghana expels Soviet technicians" would be translated in "machine readable" language for the first four of our variables in the following way: 452 660315 7200 365, where 452- Ghana (actor), 660315-March 15, 1966 (date), 7200-the event of expel 1 ing personnel , groups, or organi zations (action), and 365- the Soviet Union (target). The re1 i abi 1 i ty of the codi ng was judged qui te adequate wi th an average inter-coder re1 iabi 1 ity coefficient for all five coders across all thirty variables of .87.26 This value is quite impressive considering that each act represented thi rty separate subs tanti ve coding decisions. Obviously, each individual user of the data will have to make his own decisions as to the re1 iabi 1 i ty levels that are viewed acceptable and, therefore, which parts of the data to use. It is our conclusion, however, that the overall reliability of the data is good to excel lent.27 Dimensions of Black African Foreign Pol icy, 1964-66 Having explored a number of method01 ogi cal and conceptual concerns of the AFRICA project, let us return to the main objective of this chapter--the description and explanation of some patterns of the foreign pol icy behavior of tropical African states. As stated earlier, our entire data set consists of 14,669 foreign policy actions. These actions can be broken down into a subset of actions which represents only intra-African behavior or, in other words, actions initiated by African states toward other tropical African states. There were 4802 such actions identi fied, representing thi rty-three per cent of the total behavior of the thirty-two states in question during the time period. Another twenty-seven per cent of the behavior was directed at African non-state targets such as the O.A.U. (6.5%), U.N.E.C.A. (1.b:) and 0. C.A.M. (1.3%) and states not part of independent black Africa--Rhodesia (2.4%), Egypt (1.2%), South Africa (1 .I%) and Tunisia (0.8%). Only forty per cent of tropical African foreign pol icy behavior was directed at non- African targets in Europe and el sewhere. These figures describe the average behavior for a1 1 thi rty-two African states. In the comparative study of foreign pol icy we are less interested in average or typical behavior and more interested in variation around such averages. For example, Liberia directed fifty-one per cent of its foreign policy behavior toward other tropical African states and Upper Volta sent forty-six per cent of its behavior to these same targets. In comparison, Tanzania sent only twenty-seven per cent of its actions toward other black African states and Ghana thirty-one per cent. Why did Upper Vol ta and Liberia pay more attention to the rest of Africa than did Ghana and Tanzania? Con- versely, why were Tanzania and Ghana more interested in a "world role", as indicated by the extent of their extra-African activity? It is the exciting job of research to frame answers, often called hypotheses, that can then be tested against the facts. A possible explanation of these differences is that land-locked and/or relati vely small states wi 11 focus thei r behavior on their neighbors because of weakness and geographical vulnerability. Our AFRICA data help us think of such questions and are, of course, indispensi- ble in attempting to answer them. TABLE 1 CATEGORIES OF ACTION BETWEEN ACTORS V E R B A L ("words") i : Actor's Evaluation, Actor's Desire for Actor's Intent 1PerceptionofPast FutureActionby Regarding Own I or Current Action Target Possible future by Target Action Vis-a- Vis Target *, (3) (5) 1140 DENY (deny 31 50 DEMAND (order, 51 70 THREATEN I accusation, attribu- comnand, insist, ( threaten to ; ed action, or pol icy) demand compliance take Future I I 20 ACCUSE (charge, 3130 action unde- (make ,ired by tar- 1 ' criticize, blame, formal or informal get, with or I I disapprove, denounce, complaint) I i denigrate) without spe- I I 3100 NEGATIVE PRO- cific negative I 1020 VEGATIVE COM- POSE (offer proposal ,sanctions: a I ' MENT (comment on urge, suggest action,contingent "if I situation, explain pol icy undesired by . . .then state- , j policy undesired target) ment) I i 51 60 WARN 3090 NEGATIVE RE- (warn of a I / 11 QUEST , ask future situa- I for information, aid, action in con- tion or action I undesired by I I text undesirable to target un- I +I target) UI 1 -, desired by 21 actor) 1 o , 5110 REJECT 10' I (turn down pro- 1 I I I posal , protest, I I demand, threat; refuse, oppose, harden position) i I i I 5020 NEGATIVE I i INTENTION (ex- plain future (7) 7220 FORCE (forceful or vio- lent use of military re- sources, equipment to achieve objectives. Mi 1 i tary engagement, non-mil i tary de- struction, non-injury de- struction ) 71 80 DEMONSTRATE (armed force mobilization, movement, exercise, boycott, or walk out) demonstration, meting, display. Non-mi 1 i tary 7230 INCREASE MILITARY CAPA- BILITY (increase military spending, troop levels; de- velop weapons, authorize military action, reserve call -ups) 7240 AID OPPONENT (give mi 1 i tary aid to opponent of target) 7190 REDUCE RELATIONSHIP (cancel or postpone pl anned event, reduce routine inter- national activity, recall officials, ha1 t negotiations, break diplomatic relations) 7210 SEIZE (seize position or possessions, detain or arrest personnel ) 7200 EXPEL (expel organi za- tion, group, or personnel ) 7280 SUBVERT (aid to insur- gents, non- verbal attempts to i nfl uence i nternal pol i - pol icy unde- tics of target undesired sired by tar- by target) get TABLE 1 - CONTINUED i I V E R B A L ("words") / 2020 POSITIVE COM- MENT (comment on situation, explain policy desired by 1 target) 2040 APPROVE (praise, hail, / applaud, sup- 1 port, thank) (4) 4090 POSITIVE RE- QUEST (appeal, ask for action, aid, information, policy in context des i ra bl e to target) 4100 POSITIVE PRO- POSE (offer pro- posal, urge, sug- gest action, pol- icy desired by target) 4250 NEGOTIATE (participate in substantive talks, negotiations on specific issue or interest area) (6' 6020 POSITIVE INTENTION (ex- plain future policy desired by target) 6100 OFFER (offer to take future action desired by target) 6050 PROMISE (assure of future action desired by target) 6080 AGREE (accept pro- posal, agree to meet or negotiate, I N 0 N - V E R B A L ("deeds") 1 R (8) 8010 YIELD (surrender, submit retreat, evacuate) 8030 CONSULT-VISIT (make offici visits, participate in a meet i nvol vi ng foreign travel for least one participant, consul T with some foreign official at home or abroad) / 8060 GRANT (end negative sanctions, end confl ictful action, end threat of conflic action ; express regret, apol o gize; give invitation, asylum, privilege, diplomatic recogni tion, release, return persons property 8070 REWARD (gi ve econorni c, technical, mil itary aid) 8260 REDUCE MILITARY CAPABILI I (reduce military spending, troo ~ I agreement) I I t agree to future action, substantive / 9020 NEUTRAL COMMENT 9090 NEUTRAL REQUEST 9020 NEUTRAL I I 9100 NEUTRAL PROPOSE INTENTION level s, reduce readiness for mi1 itary action 8270 CARRY OUT AGREEMENT mentation by actor of a previ agreement, e.g., a diplomatic economic, cul tural or mi 1 i agreement . Host conferences )- 8290 INCREASE RELATIONSHIP (i crease economic, diplomatic re1 ations) 8300 ACCEPT (accept or recei v\ official visits, economic, financial , cul tural , mi 1 i tary i \ aid or support) As the other chapters in this book illustrate, one of the prime concerns of international relations is to describe and explain patterns of cooperation and conflict among states and other international actors. In order to do this, however, one must have some means of distinguishing between cooperative and conflictful behavior. In the AFRICA data set we do this by coding each foreign policy event/action into one and only one cell of Table 1. For example, take the events (1 ) "Ghana President Nkrumah denied that his government was involved in attempts to overthrow the government of Niger" and (2) "President Obote of Uganda began an official visit to West Germany." In order to code correctly each event, we ask and answer a series of questions. First, is the behavior verbal or physical? Nkrumah's denial was clearly verbal and Obote's visit was physical. We then ask with regard to the verbal behavior whether it represents an eval uation/perception, a desire or a statement of intent. Nkrumah did not express an intention toward Niger nor did he state a desire for action by Niger, so it must be an instance of an evaluation. We now know that the first event goes in column 1 of Table 1 and the second event in column 4. In order to get the correct row we ask how the target might typically view the action in question. Ordinarily states welcome officials' visits, indeed if they did not the visit could not occur, so Obote's visit is classi- fied in the bottom, cooperative row. Ordinarily, governments do not appreciate subversive behavior and denials of what they claim to be true, so Nkrumah's behavior is placed in the first, orconflict row. Nownote that by askingand answering this series of interrelated questions we have classified each event. We have decided that Nkrumah's denial is an instance of conflictful verbal evaluation, cell 1, and must be either a "negative comment", an "accuse", or a "deny". We then read the description of each of these three types of actions and conclude that 1140, DENY, best describes Nkrumah's action. Following a similar logic, Obote's trip to West Germany is considered to be best described as an instance of 8030 CONSULT-VISIT, behavior and is so coded. Each of our near- ly fifteen thousand foreign policy acts has been coded in this fashion, permit- ing us to describe patterns of African foreign pol icy cooperation and confl Table 2 dtscribes the types of foreign policy behavior tropical African states undertook vi s-a-vi s the international sys tem and the Intra-African system respectively. The thi rty-nine action types of Table 1 have been grouped into nine broader categories that range from conflictful behavior (I, 11, 111, TABLE 2 TYPES OF TROPICAL AFRICAN FOREIGN POLICY BEHAVIOR Type and Categories of Action Intra-Afri can Behavior Total Behavior N 0' N a I. Mi 1 i tary Incidents & Subversion: 1. Actions of Military Force (722) 7 2. Subversive Actions (7280) 5 3. Actions Aiding Opponents of Target Regime (7240) 0 SUBTOTALS I I . Coercion: 4. Actions Increasing Mi 1 i tary Capabi 1 i ty (7230) 5. Seizures of Personnel and Property (7210) 6. Expulsions of Individuals, Organi zations (7200) 7. Demonstrations (7180) 8. Threat Actions (5170) 9. Warnings (5160) 10. Demands for Action (3150) SUBTOTAL I1 I. Pressure: 11. Actions Reducing Relations (7190) 12. Rejections (5110) 13. Statements of Negative Intention (5020) 14. Protests (3130) 15. Hostile Proposals (3100) 16. Hostile Requests for Action (3090) 17. Denials of Action (1140) SUBTOTAL IV. Accusations: 18. Accusations (1 120) 19. Hostile Comments on Actions of Others (1020) SUBTOTAL TABLE 2 - CONTINUED Type and Categories of Action Intra-Afri can Behavior Total Behavior N ;; N V. Communication: 20. Neutral Comments on Actions of Others (9020) 448 9.3 1950 7 3.3 21. Neutral Requests for Action (9090) 53 1.1 302 2.1 22. Neutral Proposals (91 00) 83 1.7 463 - - 3.2 SUBTOTAL 'I. Consultation: 23. Negotiate (4250) 204 24. Consult-Visit (8030) 599 25. Accept Visits and Assistance (8300) 115 SUBTOTAL 91 8 19.1 2681 18.3 I. Support: 26. Positive Comments on Actions of Others (2020) 27. Approve Actions of Others (2040) 28. Positive Requests for Action (4090) 29. Posi ti ve Proposal s (41 00) 30. Statements of Positive Intention (6020) 31. Offers of Positive Action (6100) 32. Promi se Pos i ti ve Action (6050) 33. Reward with Assistance (8070) SUBTOTAL 1425 29.8 4104 27.9 I. Agreement: 34. Agree to Action (6080) 708 35. Carry Out Agreements (8270) 91 SUBTOTAL 799 16.6 2105 14.4 :X. Reconcil iation and Disengagement: 36. End Hostile Actions (Grant) (8060) 100 37. Actions Increasing Relations (8290) 90 38. Yield Positions (8010) 0 39. Actions Reducing Military Capabi 1 i ty (8260) 1 SUBTOTAL 191 4.0 479 3.3 TOTAL (N) 4802 100.0 14669 100.0 IV) through rather neutral behavior (V, VI) to cooperative behaviors (VII, VIII, IX). If one aggregates the behavior into these three broad categories one sees a strong tendency for the foreign pol icy of African states to be of a friendly--cooperative type for both total behavior (45.6%) and intra-African behavior (50.4%). Although there may be many explanations for this pattern, a few are obvious. First, African states have the least developed capacity to engage in violent conflict in comparison to all states. This limited capabi 1 i ty for violent conflict is especially prevalent in the low frequencies for nonverbal conflict behavior (I and 11) where mili tary capabilities may play a role in the formulation of this type of foreign policy. Actions involving small scale military operations, such as Mil i tary Incidents and Subversion, aimed at "destabl izing" another African regime were very rtre during this time period. Conflict did occur over Rhodesia's unilateral declaration of indepen- dence in 1965 and between Ghana and her neighbors involving alleged Ghanaian subversion, but in general it appears that African statesmen may have viewed inter-state confl ict during this early stage of economic and pol i tical development as dy~functional.~~ only two forms of conflict that occurred fairly frequently in African states' foreign pol icy were verbal confl ict behaviors--pressure and Accusation--representing 16.4 per cent and 15.4 per cent of the behavior directed respectively within the region and the international system as a whole. These patterns of action depict many of the sanctions used most frequently among African states to i nfl uence each other via rejection or mild hostile action such as closing borders, with- drawing diplomats, breaking off negotiations and cancel 1 ing or postponing planned events such as international conferences. Conflict such as this i nvol ves infl uence attempts based purely upon verbal charges and cri ticism centered on accusations of misbehavior, as in violating norms of non- interference enshrined in the O.A.U. Charter, and criticism of others' behavior via hostile comments. These forms of behavior are significant within Africa because they represent about the most violent types of conflict African states can undertake toward each other. A second possible explanation of the dominance of cooperative behavior in the foreign policies of these states may be attributed to the fact that the years 1964-66 represent the initial period of good will between African countries following the formation of the O.A.U. This dimension of behavior is seen clearly in Figure I which depicts only intra-African interactional data (N-4802). The O.A. U., which represents common African goals, provides a useful forum in which African states can establish and maintain informal contacts (communication) and involve themselves in formal consultation and presentation of positions on international and intra-Afri can issues. Over thi rty per cent of intra-African foreign pol icy behavior was produced by the communication and consultation activities of corrmenting on the behavior of others, visiting and negotiating. The amount of visiting and commenting behavior within tropical Africa is really quite high in compari- son to the behavior of all states as reported in the WEIS file, for e~arnole.~~ This suggests that during 1964-66 African statesmen were invol ved in creating an African international subsystem via 1 inkage building among the newly independent states of the continent.31 During the colonial period there was minimal contact across the Sahara and among African territories belonging to di fferent empi res as a consequence of imperial di vi de-and- rule pol icies. Beginning in the 1950s with the achievement of independence by Tunisia, Morocco, Sudan, Ghana and Guinea and intensifying in 1960 with Nigeria's independence and the numerous former French colonies' decoloniza- tion, the African continent soon comprised nearly forty states with few existing contacts. Such contacts had to be established if an African inter- national subsystem autonomous from the coloni a1 powers and other non-Afri can states and consistent wi th Pan-African aspi rations was to come i nto exi stence. The creation of the O.A.U. in 1963 was a turning point in this process, but our data also suggest that linkage-building continued at a high level after that date.32 The single most frequent type of behavior engaged in by tropical African states was Support type behavior wherein African states undertook mainly verbal support and received material assistance. Much of this support activity arises from sentiments of Pan-African sol i dari ty vi s-a-vi s the ex-metropol es and white regimes of the South and from explicit attempts to support allies and friends engaged in conflict with other African states such as the Entente states (Ivory Coast, Niger, Togo, Upper Volta and ~ahomey) vs. Nkrurnah's Ghana or Ethiopia and Kenya vs. a then irredentist Somalia. During the middle 1960s, our data clearly show the basically pacific nature of tropical African foreign relations. The Action Category, Agreement, represents actions i nvol vi ng the reaching or carrying out of international agreements. African states reach agreements on a variety of issues far more frequently than they are reported to be im- plementing previous agreements as shown in Table 2 by the differing frequencies of these two types of behavior under the general Agreement category (VIII). The general level of agreewnt by and among tropical African states was relatively high and, hence, impressive. Final ly, Reconcil iation and Disenqagement involved actions that retract or amend hostile or negative statements or actions and that close military hosti 1 i ties through withdrawal or surrender. Given the 1 imi ted nature of mi 1 i tary engagement by tropical Afri can states , no behavior yiel ding posi tion was observed and only one instance of the reduction of mili tary capability was recorded. Thus, while disarmament did not characterize African relations in this period, periodic detentes represented by ending hosti 1 e actions and increasing re1 ationships did occur in intra-African relations. Examples of thi s pattern were the reconci 1 i ation between the Entente states and Ghana after the fall of Nkrumah and the increasing integration of Sekou Toure's Guinea into the West African state system after 1962-63. Black Africa as a Set of Regional Subsystems One of the great advantages of events data is their great flexibility for use in different research contexts. Remember that each of our 14,699 actions reports who said or did what to whom during the three year period 1964-1 966. Examples a1 ready mentioned are : (a) Guinea signed a trade agreement with Hungary. (b) Ghana President Nkrumah denied that his govern- ment was involved in attempts to overthrow the government of Niger. (c) President Obote of Uganda began an official visit to West Germany. (d) After the overthrow of President Nkrumah, Ghana expels Soviet technicians. As Table 2 showed, 4,802 of these events or thirty-three per cent were initiated by one of our thirty-two African states and directed at one of the other black African states studied in our project. Thus, one may create a 32 x 32 matrix where each row represents a foreign policy actor and each column is a foreign policy target. This is done in Table 3, which represents a quantitative description of the tropical African regional subsystem during 1964-66. Let us first of all explain the organization of Table 3. Our thirty- two African states are not listed alphabetically or by size, rather they are grouped by geographical region. The fourteen states from Gambia to Nigeria represent "West Africa" ; the eight states from Cameroun to Zaire are "Central Africa"; the six states from Uganda to the Sudan are "Eastern Africa" ; and the four states from Zambia to Lesotho represent "Southern Africa". We have used this method of organization in order to better il- l ustrate the regional character of intra-Afri can re1 ations . Second, e;ch cell in Table 3 represents the actions by a row-member toward a col umn- member. Thus, the intersection of the Nigeria row and Senegal col umn shows that during this period of time Nigeria sent twelve foreign policy actions to Senegal whereas the Senegalese row and Nigerian column shows that Senegal sent sixteen acts to Nigeria, a roughly balanced relationship. Finally, the row and column totals give, for any state, the number of foreign policy acts sent or received and the number of targets of behavior and initiators of actions received. Thus Ghana, which played a leading role in intra- African affairs during this period, sent 374 acts to twenty-ei ght other African states and received 473 acts from twenty-nine states on the continent. There are 32 x 31 or 992 cells in Table 3 and only 433 or 43.6 per cent recorded any behavior during this period of time. This is a consequence of the fact that the average number of actions initiated and received was only 150 and that the average number of states that each state interacted with was only thirteen. By this measure of cohesiveness, tropical Africa was not a well-linked international subsystem between 1964 and 1966. There are, of course, few reasons to expect Chad to direct behavior at Lesotho, some 2,900 miles away or for Somalia to interact with Gabon, 2,500 miles away. It must be stressed, however, that because we show no exchange of behavior between any two states this does not mean that nothing happened between them for three years. It does mean, however, that nothing "news- worthy" happened as far as our source was concerned.33 But overall, Table 3 seems to contradict the cl ai m that tropi cal Africa represented an inter- national subsystem during 1964-66 because one of the necessary condi tions for the existence of such subsystems, regular and intense contact, is missing.34 ACTOR rn LZ < LLJ a m GAMn T A - - -4 St t.11 GAL 3 -- MTIIJR I TAN I A 1 0 WL I 2 7 G(J I NEA 14 SICHf4 L. 1 LlUtRIA 1 GtIAfJA 7 2 lVOI(Y COAST 3 UPPtK VOLTA TOGO DtlIiOME Y NIGER 11 NIGFI(1A 1 12 m CAME ROUII 6 0 GAt3Olil ru CHA[) 5 CAR COfIGO, U. f3UR(JFlrll H\.JP fl nA 7AIKE 2 U(;API [)A hi NYA 1 TAIi /AIJ I A 1 SOMAL I A LTtiIOPIA 1 4 SIJIIAII IAMB I A MALAWI GOTSWAPiA LF5IlTIIO TOTAL ACTS 15 9;) r (:ILLS 7 14 - TABLE 3 INTRA-AFRICAN FOREIGN POLICY BEHAVIOR MATRIX Quite clearly, what Table 3 does show is the very powerful influence of geographical proxini ty in i ntra-African relations. By 1 isting the states next to their geographical neighbors we see that most behavior clusters near the diagonal of the table, permitting us to identify a series of partially over1 apping regional subsys tems : 1. Senegal River states--Senegzl , Mauritania, Ma1 i and Gui nea ; 2. The West African coas t--Gui nea, Sierra Leone, Liberia, Ghana and the Ivory Coast; 3. The Conseil de 1 'Entente and its rivals--Ivory Coast, Upper Vol ta, Togo, Dahomey (Benin), Niger, Ghana and Nigeria; 4. Equatorial Africa--Cameroun, Gabon, Chad, Central African Republ ic and Congo, Brazzavi 1 le; 5. The Congo Region--Zai re, Burundi and Rwanda; 6. East Africa--Uganda, Kenya, Tanzania and Zambia; and 7. The Horn of Africa--Kenya, Somalia, Ethiopia and the Sudan. The highest cell frequencies in Table 3 are the actions of Somal ia toward Kenya (115) and Ethiopia (147). During this period the government of the Somal i Republic had an openly irredentist foreign pol icy seeking to unify a1 1 Somali-speaking people under one government. This policy was opposed by Kenya and Ethiopia because if the Somal i minorities in these two states were joined to Somalia this would have, in their view, represented an unacceptable loss of population and territory. Out of this conflict of interest, the Horn of Africa regional subsystem took shape. The second most important factor during this early post-independence period was colonial heritage. Not only did the territories of the French, British and Belgian colonial empires tend to cluster together, but specific economic, pol i tical and cul tural patterns were imposed that enhanced inter- action possi bi 1 i ties for some Afri can states and hindered interaction for others. The most fundamental cleavage in tropical Africa was 1 inguisti c, dividing the continent into English and French-speaking states--at least among the elites who formulate and implement foreign pol icy. Particularly for the francophone African states Table 3 shows a tendency to interact with each other. A third general factor is the existence or creation during 1964-66 of a functional regional organization serving the interests of regional member states. Senegal, Mauritania, Ma1 i and Guinea interact because they are mem- bers of the Organization of Senegal River States and Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda interact because of their membership in the East African Common Ser- vices Organization which was during this time frame in the process of becom- ing the East African Comuni ty. While conti nent-wide Pan-African unity re- mains a noble ideal, in the practical day-to-day affairs of development and interstate relations Africa is a continent of regions and regional organiza- tions and this fact is reflected in foreign policy behavior. Final ly, Table 3 reflects the existence of "diplomatic constellations" arising out of intra-African conflicts. Ghana under President Kwame Nkrumah stood for mi 1 i tant Pan-Africanism, state social ism and anti-imperial ism aim- ing at the removal of European influence and colonial ism from the continent. The Ivory Coast under President Houphouet-Boigny and the allied states of the Consei 1 de 1 ' Entente--Upper Vol ta, Togo, Dahomey and Ni ger--opposed Ghana's policies and there thus arose a system of foreign policy action and reaction in West Africa centering on these six states. Since the foreign policy acts in each cell may he further broken down into types of behavior, such as cooperati ve or confl ictful , Table 3 provides amp1 e opportuni ty for the detai led analysis and cornpari son of i ntra-African foreign pol icy. A second research opportunity high1 ighted by the table is the analysis of deviant cases--states that do not fit the general pattern. Four tropical African states--Ghana, Nigeria, Zaire and Ethiopia--were we1 1 linked as actors and targets to most of the other states of the continent. Mhy was this the case? While these four countries are among the largest or wealthiest on the continent, we do not think that these variables were opera- tive, except for Nigeria, the most populous of African states. Under President Nkrumah Ghana conducted an acti ve foreign pol icy in support of its Pan-Africanist and anti-imperial i st pol i cies. Thus, Ghana had more embassies throughout the continent than any other black African state. These policies and diplomatic network are reflected in Table 3. Ethiopia, on the other hand, was a center of foreign policy because of its role as host to the O.A.U. and because of the personal prestige of its Ernperior, Haile Selassie I. Zaire, then known as Congo, Kinshasa, was a focus of intra-African foreign policy because of its instability and the various foreign interventions from within and with- out the continent in its internal affairs. A feature of measuring foreign pol icy behavior we have not yet discussed is the fact that each of our foreign pol icy actions is coded as to the date at which it occurred, permitting us to make time-series profiles of foreign policy behavior. Figure 2 takes the same 4,802 intra-African foreign policy actions of Table 3 and graphs them as a frequency histogram by month. As is normal in histograms, the height of the line above each month represents the number of foreign policy acts of that type undertaken during the month in question. We have grouped behavior based on the distinctions introduced in Table 2: confl ict behavior (categories I-1, neutral behavior (category V), and cooperati ve behavior (categories VI-IX) . Thus, thi rty-six months of intra- African forei gn pol i cy are described in the fi gure. No apparent trends in any of the four types of behavior are revealed by Figure 2 over the entire three year time span. It is true that both 1965 and 1966 manifest more behavior of all types than 1964, but 1966 was not signi- ficantly more active than 1965. The one feature of considerable theoretical interest is the apparent correlation overtime of conflict and cooperative types of behavior. Note that periods of conflict behavior such as March-June 1965 and March-July 1966 are also periods of high amounts of cooperative behavior. This pattern also is revealed elsewhere in the figure where as conflict declines so does the level of cooperation. This pattern of behavior is not exclusively common to states of tropical Africa. It would appear that international crises and confl icts call forth both confl ict behavior (by definition) and cooperative behavior as statesmen consult and support one another in efforts to cope with and control events. 35 From January 1964 to October 1964 a clear downward trend occurred in i ntra-African foreign relations activity. Some confl ict was registered in August 1964, the second month of Moise Tshombe's premiership in Zaire and the month during which Stanleyvi 1 le (~isangani) fell to supporters of Gizenga and Gbenye. From Noverrber 1964 through June 1965 the trend of activity moved sharply upward as a consequence of four intra-African issues: (1) the rebel- liorl in Eastern Zaire; (2) the Fourth Afro-Asian People's Solidarity Conference in Ghana (May, 1965) which was attended by three hundred delegates representing more than seventy political organizations; (3) renewed hostilities between Ethiopia and Somalia in March 1965 and the continued struggle by Kenya against Soma1 i "shifta" ; and (4) the diplomatic offensive launched against Nkrumah's Ghana by Niger, the Ivory Coast and other West African states charging Ghana with supporting preparations for rev01 utions in these countries. The period July 1965 to January 1966 was not marked by much conflict and generally we see less behavior of all types than in early 1965 or 1966. Of course, Rhodesia's UDI did take place in November 1965, but this crucial event generated cooperati ve behavior among black African states in October 1965 within the context of the OAU Assembly and the Council of Ministers meetings. Conflict behavior, which did occur, was directed outside tropical Africa to the whi te-ruled South and Great Britain. Beginning in February 1966 the trend again turned upward as a consequence of coups d'etat in Nigeria (twice) and Ghana and the constitutional crisis in Uganda (February) where Obote suspended the constitution because of an alleged "coup". In the case of the fa1 1 of power of Kwame Nkrurnah in Feb- ruary 1966, large amounts of cooperative behavior were directed toward Ghana by Nkrumah's former opponents while Sekou Toure's Guinea, where Nkrumah care to reside, conflicted heavily with Ghana and to a lesser extent the Ivory Coast for the remainder of the year. After July 1966 the trend again turns downward until the end of our time period is reached in December. There does seem to be some periodicity in Figure 2 in that the first six months of each year register more behavior than in the last six months. Why this is so is not clear, for while the U.N. General Assembly meets each fall in New York and may thus draw attention away from intra-African problems, the OAU Assembly of Heads of State and Government also meets in the fa1 1, which one would expect to produce intra-African behavior. There is, of course, a danger in positing trends or regular periods of high and low activity levels based on relatively short time series. We would need data covering ten or more years before we would be willing to make general statements about the behavior of African foreign policy overtime. While space limitations prevent us from so doing in this chapter, readers should recognize that figures such as Figure 2 could be created for any single African state or for any subset of these states and since the AFRICA data were collected on a daily basis the time interval used can be days, weeks, months, quarters or whatever time unit is of interest to the researcher. We view this time-series aspect of foreign policy event data to be one of its principal advantages because it permits us to ask and answer basic questions relating to stability - and change in foreign policy behavior. Patterns of Black African Foreign Pol icy Having explored the dimensions of black African foreign pol icy and the regional subsystems within tropical Africa, we will not attempt to answer a number of questions concerning general patterns in their behavior. As Albert Camus once noted, there is no truth, only truths. This is certainly the case when one attempts to answer inquiries about a state's foreign policy. No single explanatory scheme, such as "power pol i tics" or Marxist dialectical materialism, can cover all aspects of this phenomenon. This is so because the foreign policy of a nation is an extraordinarily broad and complex happening. Thus, in what follows we encourage readers to come up with their own explana- tions of African foreign policy behavior which, as hypotheses, they can test and compare to our findings. Table 4 reports the absolute and relative frequency of the foreign policy behavior of each of the thirty-two states in the AFRICA project. The first col umns represent total behavior directed to all targets and the columns on the right report behavior di rected toward other tropical African states. Thus, Tanzania was the most active state, initiating 1,233 foreign pol icy acts over this three year period, fifty-three times more behavior than the least active state, Botswana. Tanzania's behavior represents 8.4 per cent of all behavior observed and Botswana's actions are only 0.2 per cent of all behavior. The most active state in intra-African relations was Ghana with 374 actions, 7.8 per cent of the total intra-African behavior and Botswana, which only be- came independent in September 1966, was again the least active. Table 4 clearly neither distinguishes between the types of foreign pol icy actions each state undertook, nor does it inform us about who were the targets of their actions. However, even at this aggregate level, the table does perrni t us to distinguish between active and passive states. The ten most active states, from Tanzania to Zaire, account for 57.6 per cent of all behavior and 56.1 per cent of intra-African behavior. The ten most passive states, from Malawi to Botswana, represent only 8.4 per cent and 9.9 per cent of the same behaviors. This means that Tanzania or Ghana individually initiated nearly as much foreign policy actions as the combined totals of these ten least active states. Now, why is it that some African states are comparatively active in foreign affairs and others are relatively passive? Note that such a question could neither be asked nor could it be answered without comparative foreign policy TABLE 4 AFRICA PROJECT ACTORS AND THEIR FOREIGN POLICY FREQUENCIES, 1964-66 Total Behavior (n = 14669) Intra-African Behavior (n = 4802) STATE absol ute relative absol ute relative frequency frequency frequency frequency Tanzania Ghana Zarnb i a Kenya Soma1 ia Ni geri a Uganda Ethiopia Senegal Zai re Ivory Coast Niger Gui nea Ma1 i Sudan Dahomey (Benin) To go Mauritania Upper Vol ta Cameroun Congo Republ i c Sierra Leone Ma1 awi Chad C.A.R. Liberia Burundi Gabon Rwar; da Lesotho Gamb i a Botswana mean std. dev. 1 data as provided by the AFRICA project data set. Second, such a question is just what the comparative analysis of foreign pol icy is designed to , answer. We have here a variable, the frequency of foreign pol icy behavior of each African state during 1964-66, given in the left hand column of Table 1 4. Can we think of other variables that may be related to this measure of activity so that we can "explain" foreign policy activity by demonstrating such a re1 ationship? Scientific or comparative research on foreign pol icy represents nothing more complicated than establishing relations between variables and developing theoretical explanations of why they exist. 36 Let us be "deductive" and attempt first of all to theorize about what may "cause" some African states to be active and others passive in foreign t affairs. Frequently, scholars attempt to explain foreign pol icy variables I on the basis of features of the individual leaders of nations. Hence, Presi- I dent Kwame Nkrurnah's Pan-African proposals for a "continental union Govern- I ment" for Africa probably had an impact on Ghana's foreign pol icy as did I Emperor Haile Selassie's longevity and prestige on Ethiopia's foreign actions. Explanations of foreign pol icy that use the characteristics of lead- ers involve what James N. Rosenau has called "individual" variables.37 In our view, because the individual characteristics of leaders are so difficult to a better starting point is the character of the acting state, such as its size, wealth or political system. When one uses such variables in an effort to explain foreign pol icy one is involved with "national attri- butes" as explanatory factors. In cost-benefit terms we suggest that students should attempt to explain the foreign behavior of states by these national attribute characteristics of states and then look at individual variables only when attributes fail to do the job. 39 What features of African states, then, may "cause" them to be compara- tively active or passive in foreign policy? Quite often answers to a question such as this are suggested by thinking about the nature of the phenomenon we are trying to explain. To be "active" in foreign affairs implies that the state has the capacity or capability to act frequently. That is, while a state may have the capacity to undertake an active foreign policy and choose not to use this capacity and thus be passive, if a state has an active policy profile it must have the capacity to produce such frequent behavior. All other things being equal, then, the greater a state's capability to conduct foreign policy, the more active will be its foreign policy. Now capability may take various forms, but certainly the extent of available resources and an extensive diplomatic network contribute to a state's capacity to under- take foreign pol icy. We can "measure" resources by recording each black African state's Gross Domestic Product in 1965 and its diplomatic network by the number of diplomats it sent abroad in 1963-64. Our measure of foreign policy activity is taken from Table 4. Having decided how to measure or "operationalize" our concepts of capacity and foreign policy activity, we may state our research hypotheses: HI The greater the resources a state possesses, the more active will be its foreign policy. Hz The more extensive a state's diplomatic network is, the more active will be its foreign policy. HO There is no relationship between resources or diplomatic networks and foreign pol icy activity. This last hypothesis is the "null hypothesis". If we can show that it is false, this implies that H1 and Hp are probably correct for these African states during this time period. There are many procedures that can be used to "test" hypotheses such as ours; Table 5 represents one such approach known as cross-tabulation. We have converted our quantitative information on the number of foreign policy actions, the dollar value of G.D.P., and the number of diplomats abroad into rank orders. Thus, the Sudan had a comparatively "large" G.D.P. in 1965 and was "moderately active" in foreign policy between 1964 and 1965. When each of our thirty-two states is given the appropriate score on G.D.P. and foreign policy activity it may be classified into one and only one cell of the 3 x 3 table. Study of Table 5 should convince any reader that there is a clear pattern with twenty-one of thirty-two states in the three diagonal cells running from large and active to small and passive. Eleven states do not fit the pattern exactly, with the Somali Republic being the most "deviant case", in that it had a small G.D.P. but was in the top ten most active state category. It should be clear, then, that cross-classification tables such as Table 5 permit researchers to see patterns-- resources are positively related to foreign policy activity -- and to identify exceptions to our general izations that require further research, possibly of a case study sort.40 How "strong" i s the relationship between resources and activity described TABLE 5 THE RELATIOI(St1IP BETWEEN RESOURCES AND FOREIGN POLICY ACT1 VITY - -- ---- _ _-.____p Gross Domestic Product, 1965(~) Extent of Activity - - La rge -------- Medi urn Srna 1 1 N GHANA UGANDA SOMALIA NIGERIA Active ETHIOPIA ZAIRE TAN ZAN I A KENYA SENEGAL ZAMB I A 8 1 1 10 SUDAN CAMEROUN CONGO, B. IVORY COAST NIGER TOGO DAHOMEY MAURITANIA UPPER VOLTA GUINEA MAL I Moderately Active 2 -- 6 3 11 SIERRA LEONE BURUNDI MALAW I CAR CHAD GABON LIBERIA GAMBIA RWANDA LESOTHO BOTSWANA Passive SOURCES: (a) Calculated from Table 4. (b) Fro111 Donald G. Morrison, et. al., Black Africa: . A Coxarative Handbook (New York: Free Press, 1972), p. 50. NOTE : Gacl~rr~a . 80 . in Table 5? Descriptive statistics perrni t us to answer such questions. One such statistic is Gamma, a measure of the degree of association or correlation between two rank ordered variables .41 The formula for Gamna G = p$! , where P represents the number of rank agreements and () the number of rank, disagree- ments. For example, there are eight cases in the large-active cell and twenty cases in the four cells below and to the right of this cell. Mu1 tiplying 8 x 20 gives 160, which is the first element of P. To get the first element of Q note that there are only two cases in the two cells below and to the left of Uganda ' s cell, giving 1 x 2 = 2. Working our way through Table 5 in this fashion (rather than having the computer do it for us which is normal) pro- duces the fol lowing calculations : Thus, for Table 5 Gamma is .8. Gamma can range from .O indicating no rela- tionship to +1.0 or -1.0 indicating perfect direct or indirect associations; we may conclude that the relationship between resources and activity is strong and direct as predicted by our first hypothesis. Table 6 repeats this exercise for the second of our hypotheses, that diplomatic networks will be directly related to foreign pol icy activity. The pattern is not as evident as in the previous test and this is reflected in the low value of Gamma, .32. The reason we find little support for our second hypothesis is that the newly independent Eastern African states had few diplomats but active foreign policies (the few-active cell) and because the "old" African state of Liberia had many diplomats but a cautious and passive foreign pol icy during this time period. It would appear, then, that our first hypothesis is strongly supported but that our second hypothesis receives only weak support. What about the null hypothesis of no re1 ationship between capabi 1 i ty and foreign pol icy acti vi ty? We hope, of course, to show that this null hypothesis is false so that we may infer that our two research hypotheses are true for these states during this time period. The way we try to show that nu1 1 hypothesis is wrong is by cal- culating the level of statistical significance of each of our observed Gamnas, TABLE 6 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DIPLOMATIC NETWORK AND FOREIGN POLICY ACTIVITY Number of Diplomats Abroad, 1963-64(~) Extent Activi ty Many Few Active GHANA ZAIRE TAN ZAN I A NIGERIA SOMAL IA KENYA ETHIOPIA ZAMBIA SENEGAL UGANDA Moderately Acti ve CAMEROUN NIGER MAURITANIA MAL I CONGO, B. SUDAN UPPER VOLTA IVORY COAST DAHOMEY GUINEA TOGO 5 5 1 11 --- LIBERIA SIERRA LEONE GABON BURUNDI GAMB I A CAR RWANDA CHAD MALAW I LESOTHO BOTSWANA Passive GAMMA = .32 - . - - - .- -- --- - -- - ----- -- - SOURCES: (a) Calculated fro111 Table 4. (b) Froni Morrison, et.al., - Black -- Africa, p. 153. NOTE : Garr~ma = .32. .80 and -32. What this means is quite simple. Look again at Table 5 where resources and activity are related. The strength of this relationship as measured by Gamma is .80. Now, what "caused" this relationship to be as it is? We would like to believe that the association exists because our reasoning was correct and our first hypothesis is true, resources "cause" foreign pol icy activity. However, another possible "cause" of the pattern shown in Table 5 is mere chance. That is to say, for these thirty-two states during this time period resources I are not causally related to foreign pol icy activity and therefore, the association we see and index by calculating Gamna is the simple consequence of a random distribution of the cases into the nine cells. Another way of stating this is that if countries are assigned to each cell on a random basis, then each cell wi 11 receive one-ninth or between three and four countries. This obviously did not happen in Table 5, so when we do a test of significance on Gamma we determine the probabi 1 i ty that mere chance produced the observed distribution. If this probabi 1 i ty is quite small , say less than .05, we may say the nu1 1 hypothesis of no relationship is false. The calculation of the significance of Gamna is too lengthy for this chapter,42 so we merely report that for Table 5 it is .0004 and for Table 6 it is .19. Thus, only four times in ten thousand would chance produce the relationship seen in Table 5. We may therefore reject the null hypothesis for resources and regard our first hypothesis as "true" until new evidence shows it to be "wrong". For Table 6, on the other hand, random assignment could produce this pattern nineteen times in a hundred. While chance apparently does not seem to be a big factor, it is greater than the conventional five times in one hundred, so we cannot reject the null hypothesis and we must conclude that our second hypothesis con- cerning diplomatic networks is probably "wrong". We have now shown how the AFRICA project data may be used to do comparative or scientific studies of foreign policy. We began with an observation--that some African states were active and others were passive in their overall foreign pol icy behavior. We then asked why this was so and proposed a theoretical explanation based on the notion that states with the capacity to undertake an acti ve forei gn pol icy woul d have such pol icies. We then "operational i zed" our concepts by using frequency of actions to measure foreign pol icy activity and Gross Domestic Product and diplomats abroad to measure two different aspects of capacity--resources and diplomatic networks. The next step was to observe the relationships among these three variables by constructing Tables 5 and 6 and calculating Gamna. Having found a "strong" relation between activity and resources and a "weak" relation between activity and diplomacy, we evaluated the null hypothesis via tests of statistical significance. We concluded by determi ni ng from the accumul ated evi dence that resources probably do faci 1 i ta te an active foreign policy (accepting Hi) but that diplomatic networks probably play no role in fostering an active foreign policy (rejecting Hz). All of this should be treated as an example, in that many readers are probably not interested in what explains differences between active and passive African states.43 The point is to encourage you to create foreign pol icy variables that interest you and to get you then to attempt to explain African foreign policy behavior in the comparative manner we have just illustrated. As one of us has shown elsewhere,44 this process of asking and answering corn- parati ve questions about foreign pol icy behavior can produce important advances in our understanding of international relations. Let us now look somewhat more briefly at three more patterns of black African foreign pol icy during the middle 1960s: intra-African conflict, the targets of African foreign pol icy behavior, and the individual and organ- izational initiators of this behavior. Table 7 reports the frequency by country of confl ict behavior among our thi rty-two states. During 1964-66 these states initiated 885 conflict acts, or 18.4 per cent of the 4,802 total intra-African actions. The Somali Republic was by far the most conflictful state during this period because it undertook forty-four more conflict actions than Ghana, the second ranking state, and particularly because forty-six per cent of its behavior was of the conflict type, the next highest percentage being Burundi's 29.3 per cent. Tanzania is an interesting exception. By volume its thirty-six conflict events make it one of the ten most conflictful states, but this was only 10.8 per cent of Tanzania's total intra-African behavior, which is considerably below average for a1 1 thirty-two states. Again, Table 7 suggests many questions, one of which is why do some African states undertake more foreign policy conflict behavior than others? There are two explanations that are frequently cited in the literature on foreign pol icy behavior. The fi rst is that domestic confl ict fosters external conflict.45 The idea here is that elites confronted with internal instability and violence wi 11 attempt to reduce wi thin-group conflict by undertaking conflict with out- groups, i .e., other states. El i tes do this, often call ed "scapegoating", be- cause it is frequently observed that when members of a group are conflicting 224 TASLE 7 TABLE 7: INTRA-AFRICAN CONFLICT BEHAVIOR, 1964-66 Absol ute Z of Total Rank Country Val ue Intra-African Confl ictual Behavior 1. Soma1 ia 142 46.0 2. Ghana 3. 98 26.2 Kenya 4. 76 22.0 Zaire (Congo, K.) 60 5. 24.5 6. Uganda 45 18.8 7. Niger 42 23.5 8.5 Tanzania 36 10.8 8.5 To go 36 19.6 10. Guinea 35 25.8 11. Upper Vol ta 30 19.8 12. Ivory Coast 27 10.6 13. Burundi 24 29.3 14. Dahoney (Benin) 21 13.3 15.5 Nigeria 18 10.8 15.5 Sudan 18 10.4 17. Zarnb i a 17 7.9 18.5 Chad 15 14.7 18.5 Senegal 15 10.7 20.5 Congo, Brazzaville 13 20.0 20.5 Malawi 13 23.6 22. Rwanda 11 15.9 23. Central African Rep. 10 11.8 24. f4a 1 i 9 6.3 25.5 Liberia 6 6.3 25.5 Sierra Leone 6 6.6 27. Cameroun 4 4.9 28.5 Gabon 3 9.7 28.5 Mauritania 3 5.0 30. Lesotho 1 10.0 31.5 Botswana 0 0.0 31.5 Garnb i a 0 0.0 TOTAL 885 100.0% with an external enemy they limit or end conflict within the group. A second possible explanation is based on a simple stimulus-response model called "tit- for-tat". According to this argument, if states receive confl ict behavior from other states they will then respond in kind. Foreign pol icy el ites behave in this fashion for a variety of reasons--because the most effective counter to force is superior force, because such behavior has been learned and agrees with the rules of the diplomatic game, and because they lack sufficient imagi- nation to do otherwise. We thus have two competing hypotheses designed to explain foreign pol icy conflict behavior among African states: Hi The greater the domestic conflict an African state experiences, the more foreign conflict it wi 11 undertake. Hz The greater the foreign conflict an African state receives, the more foreign conflict it will undertake. We also have the null hypothesis: HO There is no relation between domestic conflict or received foreign conflict and foreign conflict behavior among African states. We shall use the first column of Table 7 to measure foreign conflict behavior sent to other African states and another part of the AFRICA data to measure the extent of conflict received. Domestic conflict is measured by the total number of deaths from domestic violence in the five year period, 1961-1965.~~ Tables 8 and 9 present the results of our test of the preceding hypotheses. There is at best only a moderate relationship between domestic conflict and foreign conflict, for only sixteen of thirty-two states are on the expected high-high to low-low diagonal. Deviant cases are Togo and Guinea that had little domestic conflict between 1961 and 1965 but had high foreign conflict and Rwanda and Cameroun where the reverse pattern is observed. Gamma equals .43 which is in the correct direction, but it is not significant at the .05 level, so we cannot reject the null hypotheses as regards domestic conflict and decide that Hi is probably "wrong". Two points should be made with regard to Table 8. First, our finding agrees with considerable previous research that found little or no relationship between domestic and foreign conflict when states other than African countries were ~tudied.4~ Second, our hypothesis would have been supported if the four deviant cases had not occurred. The TABLE 8 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DOMESTIC CONFLICT ADD FOREIGN CONFLICT - - - - - - - - - - -- - - - - . -- - ---- --A - ---- - - - - - - . - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - --- . - -- - -- - - - Deaths From Domes tic Violence, 1961-65 Conf 1 ict Actions Sent , 1964- 66 Hi gh Medi urn Low N - -- -- ---- - -- -- KENYA SOMAL IA TOGO ZAIRE GHANA GUINEA ETHIOPIA NIGER UGANDA TANZANIA BURUNDI NIGERIA SUDAN ZAMBIA Medi unl DAHOMEY UPPER VOLTA CHAD IVORY COAST SENEGAL CONGO, B. MALAW I RWANDA GABON C.A.R. CAMEROUN LESOTHO MAL I LIBERIA SIERRA LEONE Low MAURITANIA BOTSWAPJA GAMB I A 2 2 7 11 ----- --- ---- ----A- - N 10 11 11 SOURCE: C. L. Taylor and M. C. Hudson, --- Handbook of Pol i tican - and Social Indicators, 2nd. ed. (New Haven: Yale University Press, 19721, pp. 110-115. NOTE: Gamnia = .43, p = .07. TABLE 9 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FOREIGN CONFLICT RECEIVED AND SENT - - -- - - -- - - - - - ______ - -_ I_ -- - ----- -- -- - Conflict Actions Received, 1964-66 Confl ict Actions ZAIRE Hi gh ETHIOPIA TANZANIA GUINEA 7 / 7 1 'In I IU BURUNDI IVORY COAST UPPER VOLTA SUDAN DAHOMEY CHAD CONGO, B. NIGERIA SENEGAL ZAMBIA Med i urn MALAW I Gamma = .82 p .001 Low RWANDA C.A.R. MAL I BOTSWANA SIERRA LEONE LEBERIA MAURITANIA CAMEROUN GABON GAMB I A LESOTHO -- - ----- 0 - 2 ---_- _ --_ 9 11 --. - - --. - --- N - - - - - - - - - -- -- 10 9 13 32 -- -- - --- __ question naturally arises as to why Rwanda, Cameroun, Togo and Guinea do not fit the overall pattern. Comparative case studies of Rwanda and Cameroun on the one hand and Guinea and Togo on the other hand are clearly suggested by Table 8. Therefore, if a hypothesis fails to receive support this result is not necessarily "bad". Often the most we can hope to achieve is the rejection of plausible but factually incorrect hypotneses. Such results unquestionably do enhance our understandi ng of forei gn pol i cy behavior. Table 9 provides striking support for our second hypothesis that conflict received is associated with conflict behavior undertaken. The va1 ue of Gama is positive and large, twenty-one of thirty-two cases are on the diagonal, and chance could produce such a distribution less than once in a thousand times. Our only sharply deviant case is again Togo which received little foreiqn con- flict (one act) but undertook a high level of conflict behavior (thirty-si~ acts). This may be explained when wenote that seventy-eight per cent of Togo's conflict activity was directed at its neighbor to the west, Ghana. A border dispute with Ghana over the Ewe people who 1 ive in both countries and charges of Ghanaian interference in Togolese domestic affairs led Togo to be a relatively high conflict initiator. It would appear, then, that our second hypothesis, the "ti t-for-tat" theory, is supported for these states during this time period. Since it would appear that there is a strong tendency for African states to send conflict to other African states on the basis of the conflict actions they receive from these same states, let us look somewhat more deeply at this pattern. Table 10 presents the twenty-one pairs or dyads of African states that recorded ten or nore conf:ict behaviors between 1964 and 1966. Thus, Soma1 ia sent si xty-nine confl ict acts to Ethiopia, making this the single most confl ictful dyad whereas Zambia sent ten such acts to Ghana. Table 10 tells us a great deal about intra-African foreign policy conflict in the middle 1960s. First, these twenty-one dyads account for sixty-five per cent of all the conflict behavior within tropical Africa at this time, a very large proportion when we remember that there are 992 such pairs of states. Second, note that sixteen out of twenty-one dyads are contiguous, illustrating the fact that African states mainly conflict with bordering states. Conflict at a distance, particularly the most intense forms such as mi1 i tary incidents, subversion and coercion, is infrequent. Thi rd, examination of the AFRICA data indicates that during this time period there were two main types of confl ict behavior--border issues and interference in internal politics. Some states, such as Somalia TABLE 10 ~ DYADIC CONFLICT IN TROPICAL AFRICA, 1964-66 ~ Military Contiguous Incidents, All Conflict 1 k Dya d States Subversion, Acts Type of Conflict And Coercion Somalia Ethiopia Somalia Kenya Ghana Guinea Ethiopia Sornal ia Kenya Soma1 i a Niger Ghana Togo Ghana Upper Vol ta Ghana Zaire Congo, B. Uganda Zaire Guinea Ghana Burundi Rwanda Zaire Burundi Ivory Coast Ghana Dahorney Niger Yes Yes No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Border, irredentist Border, i rredenti st Interference, defensive Border, defens i ve Border, defensi ve Interference, defensi ve Interference, offensive & defensive Interference, defensive Interference, defensi ve Interference, offensi ve Interference, offensive Interference, offensi ve Interference, offensi ve Interference, defensive Border, i rreden ti s t Chad Sudan Yes 5 12 Border, defensive Malawi Tanzania Yes 2 11 Interference, defensi ve Ghana Zaire No 1 11 Interference, offensive Rwanda Burundi Yes 0 11 Interference, defensive Ivory Coast Guinea Yes 3 10 Interference, defensive Zambia Ghana No 0 10 Interference, defensive TOTAL 6 1 578 ~ 1s '? OF ALL SUCH ACTS DURING 1964-1 966 and Dahomey, claimed territory or pooulations "beloncjing" to neighboring states A and thus were irredentist. Others, such as Ethiopia, Kenya an3 Chad, defended their possessions. We see here in tropical Africa the classical pattern of I territorial ly revisionist vs. territorially status quo powers. The most frequent high conflict issue, fifteen out of twenty-one cases, was over sovereignty and non-interference in domestic affairs. This arose from two somewhat different processes. First, certain states such as Ghana and Burundi sought to change the domestic and foreign pol i cies or personnel of neighboring states via conflict of an offensively interfering sort which i tended to provoke defensive conflict by Niger, Togo, Upper Volta, Zaire and the Ivory Coast. The second pattern was when internal instability or a coup d'etat created situations where other African states got involved in a7 effort to bring to power friends or to attack those who removed from power friends and allies. This explains Guinea's conflict with Ghana after the overthrow of President Nkrumah and most of Zaire's conflict linkages. We think, then, that Table 10 illustrates well the fundamental question asked in comparative I research on foreign pol icy--"of what larger pattern is this behavior an in~tance?"~8 -- - Each time this question receives a plausible answer students and researchers wi 11 I have achieved considerable progress in understanding and explaining the forei gn ~ pol icy behavior being studied. There were 220 targets toward which our thirty-two African states sent behavior between 1964 and 1966. Table 11 reports in a rank order fashion the forty-si x targets that received one hundred or more foreign pol icy actions during this period. Note that nearly seventy-four per cent of African foreign policy behavior was sent to just twenty-one percent of the target:, illustrating the concentrated nature of this foreign policy behavior. The targets fall into several meaningful categories. First are the "top dog" nations including the major colonial powers and their political and economic allies such as the United States, ~ West Germany and Japan. It has been suggested that dependent, "underdog" nations will interact more with powerful metropolitan top dog nations than with each 1 other .49 Our data certainly do not contradict this proposition, even though the second most important category of targets is other African states ranging from Ghana to Burundi. The thi rd category compri ses the two major communist states-- the People's Republic of China and the Soviet Union. Together they received nearly five per cent of African foreign pol icy behavior during this time period whereas the TABLE 11 THE TARGETS OF AFRICA!$ FOREIGX POLICY BEHAVIOR, 1964-1965 Rank ia rge t Acts f Un i ted Ki ngdorn Ghana France "Africa" United States People's Republ ic of China Organization of African Unity Rhodesia Zai re Kenya Ethiopia U.S.S.R. Tanzania O.A.U. Heads of State Conference O.A. U. Council of Ministers Gui nea U.N. Economic Com. for Africa Uganda Niger West Germany O.C.A.M. Sornal ia European Econorni c Comnuni ty Nigeria Egypt (U.A. R. ) Uni ted Nations Organization Ivory Coast Zambia Consei 1 de 1 ' Entente Sudan Eas t Afri ca Republ ic of South Africa Cornonweal th of Nations Portugal llpper Vol ta Ma1 i "Nestern" countries Tunisia Be1 gium Togo U. N. misc. organs Da homey Chad Burundi East African C.S.O. Japan Unclear Targets 21 6 1.5 Other ~argets (N = 173) 3659 24.9 Total 14669 100.0 ---- NOTE : Total number of targets = 220. western capital ist countries, including the former colonial powers, received nearly fifteen per cent. This ratio of 3:l indicates the absence of non- a1 igned foreign pol icies in tropical Africa during the middle 1960s. African states were "pro-Western" in their behavior patterns.50 The fourth type of target comprises international organizations of a uni versa1 type (U.N. ) , con- tinental type (O.A.U.) and regional type (O.C.A.M.) of importance to African states. One of the major sources of African states' power and influence in international affai rs is thei r role in international organizations and this is reflected in their behavior. Finally, the fifth category contains other African states not part of independent black Africa during 1964-66 such as Rhodesia, South Africa, Egypt and Tunisia. Action was, of course, directed at the white minority regimes of Southern Africa as part of the struggle for majority rule and decol oni za tion in that region. Arab-speaki ng northern African states received attention from sub-Saharan African states because of the Arab role in the O.A.U. and in intra-African linkage building. It should be remembered that Table 11 summarizes the behavior of all thirty- two African states in our project. Working with the AFRICA data, students and researchers could construct a series of such tables for individual African states which would permit a whole series of fascinating comparative research questions to be asked and answered. We again stress that in this chapter we can only illustrate the character and a small part of the research potential of the AFRICA data, primarily in an effort to stimulate students to do compara- ti ve studies of African foreign pol icy behavior themsel ves. The final variable we shall present from our data is information on who actual ly initiated each foreign pol icy action. Table 12 reports this information for all behavior and for intra-African behavior. One weakness of event data is immediately apparent in the table, the fact that sources of events frequently do not report which office or member of a government undertook the action. Rather, they say "Guinea signed a trade treaty with Hungary. " or "Ghana cl osed i ts border with Togo. " In such circumstances we can only code that the "State or Society" initiated the behavior, which represents 29.3 per cent of all behavior in our data set. However, for the remaining 70.7 per cent of behavior we do know who it was ~ that acted for the state. TABLE 12 FOREIGN POLICY ACTOR CATEGORY Events Source of Event Total Behavior Intra-Africa Behavior Absol ute Relative Absol ute Relative Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency Head of State 5492 37.4 1843 38.4 State or Society 4294 29.3 1 1 36 23.7 Foreign Minister 921 6.3 331 6.9 Misc. Minister 846 5.8 328 6.8 Gov' t. as a Whole 70 0 4.8 2 74 5.7 Official Delegation 659 4.5 335 7.0 Finance Minister 41 9 2.9 53 7.1 Diplomat Ambassador 390 2.7 153 3.2 Unspecified Individual 209 1.4 102 2.1 Exec. Department 156 1.1 45 0.9 Official of Exec. 128 0.9 48 1.0 Organization 104 0.7 27 0.6 Defense Mini ster 86 0.6 46 1 .O An Indi vi dual 7 1 0.5 10 0.2 Legislature as a Whole 40 0.3 13 0.3 Mi 1 i tary Forces 40 0.3 24 0.5 Member of Legislature 35 0.2 12 0.2 Group of Individuals 26 0.2 6 0.1 Group of Organizations 26 0.2 4 0.7 Mi 1 i tary Official 15 0.1 6 0.7 Pol i tical Party Officer 12 0.1 6 0.1 Total 14669 4802 In tropical Afri ca where the bureaucratic organi zations that manage forei gn affairs are small and new,51 individuals, particularly heads-of-state and foreign ministers, take most foreign pol icy actions. Organizations, groups and other individuals are far less important, except that in i ntra-African affairs official delegations are used frequently as foreign policy actors. Also note that finance ministers are not very important within Africa but rather frequent representa- tives of their states in general foreign affairs. Why is it then, that official delegations are important in one arena and finance ministers in another? Why is it that heads-of-state initiate nearly forty per cent of all African foreign pol icy behavior? Why is it that executive departments such as foreign ministries are relatively unimportant actors? Studies of the bureaucratic pol i tics and organizational process aspects of forei gn pol icy behavior are designed to pro- vide answers to such questions .52 We shall neither summarize that 1 i terature nor attempt answers to the above questions at this time. We do, however, invite students to read into this literature, to use the AFRICA data to construct tables like Table 12 for sets of African states of interest to them, and then to ask and attempt to answer comparative questions about this intriguing aspect of African foreign policy. Concl usion As we noted at the outset of this chapter, the foreign policy behavior of a nation is an extremely complex matter to describe and explain in a systematic fashion. If we think of a state's foreign policy as the external goals its leaders establ ish and the actions they take to achieve these goals, then we are confronted with great difficulties in gathering information about goals and actions. There are, however, a variety of types of data that may be used to achieve this purpose: (1 ) votes in international organizations ; (2) memberships in organizations, all iances and treaties; (3) transactions of goods (trade and aid), people (tourism and students) and i deas (news service subscriptions , book translations, letters) ; (4) surveys of mass and elite attitudes on foreign affairs; (5) networks of diplomatic representation; (6) themati c perceptions as revealed in speeches of leaders; (7) simulations of behavior by nationals of the countries i nvol ved; (8) decisions made by leaders; and (9) actions actually undertaken by the states. While all of these data types are useful, the AFRICA project chose to work with actions as described in "newsworthy" events reported in a pub1 ic chronology-- Africa Research Bulletin. Event data are clearly most directly related to the foreign policy actions of states and since many events report verbal desires and intentions (see Tables 1 and Z), they are a good source of information on goals as well. Host of this chapter has involved a description of how the AFRICA event data were made and i 11 ustrations of how these data can be used to describe African foreign policy behavior and to explain that behavior as well. Since our data include 14,699 events by thirty-two states or forty-three political regimes, each event being coded for thirty different variable attributes, we could only scratch the surface of the AFRICA project data in this report. Other uses that have been made of the AFRICA data involve descriptions of basic foreign pol icy at terns ,53 studies of how national cultural attributes relate to behavior,54 the analysis of foreign conflict, participation and dependence among African states ,55 and tests of status-field theory. 56 Since the AFRICA data are publ ic,57 anyone may acqui re them for thei r own research. The study of African international re1 ations does not merely invol ve reading textbooks such as this. Students should not just consume knowledge about African foreign policy, they should try to produce such knowledge themselves. If this chapter has stimulated some readers to use the AFRICA data in their own research, we wi 11 have achieved our purpose and we wish you luck in your research! END NOTES Johan Galtung, "The Social Sciences: An Essay on Polarization and Inte- gration," in-K. Knorr and J .l. Rosenau, eds. ,- Contending Approaches to International Politics (Princeton: Princeton Uni versi tv Press. 1969). Some of the better case studies are: A. K. Akinyemi , Foreign Pol icy and Federal ism: The Ni qerian Experience (Ibadan: Ibadan University Press, 1974) ; J. Barber, South Africa's Foreign Pol icy, 1945-1970 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1973) ; C. Hoskyns, "Africa's Foreign Relations : The Case of Tanzania," International Affairs 44 (July 1966) : 446-462; G. Idana. Niaeria: Internal Politics and Foreian Pol icy, 1960-1966 J - d d (Ibadan: Ibadan University Press, 1974) ; K. Ingham, ed. , Foreign Relations of Afri can States (London : Butterworth, 1974) ; C. McMas ter, Ma1 awi : Foreiqn Policy and Development (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1974); S. Nolutshungu, South Africa in Africa (New York: Africana Press, 19;4) ; W.A.E. Skurni k, The Foreign Pol icy of Senegal (Evanston: Northwestern University Press, 1972); W.S. Thompson, Ghana's Foreign Pol icy, 1957-1966 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969) ; J. E. Spence, Republ ic under Pressure: A Study of South African Foreign Policy (London: Oxford Uni- versity Press, 1965); A. Vandenbook, South Africa and the World (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1970) ; J. Pettman, Zambia: Security and Conflict (New York: Africana, 1974). The 1 i terature on the comparati velscientific study of foreign pol icy has grown rapidly in recent years. Starting points are: James N. Rosenau, The Scientific Study of Foreign Pol icy (New York: Free Press, 1971 ) ; Patrick J. McGowan and Howard B. Shapiro, The Comparative Study of Foreign Pol icy: A Survey of Scientific Findings (Beverly Hi 11 s : Sage Publ i cations, 1973); James N. Rosenau, ed., Comparing Foreign Pol icies: Theories, Findinqs, and Methods (New York: Hal sted Press, 1974) ; Charles W. Kegley, Jr., et. a1 . , eds., International Events and the Comparative Analysis of Foreign Pol icy (Col umbia: Uni versi t-y of South Carol ina Press, 1975) ; and chapters in Patrick J. McGowan, eb., Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Pol icy Studies (Beverly Hi 11s: Sage Publ ications, annual since 1973). A. Brecht, Pol i tical Theory (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1959), pp. 113-116. All requests for the AFRICA data should be sent to: The Inter-[lniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research, P.O. Box 1248, Ann Arbor, Michigan, 48106, U.S.A., attention I.R. Archive. See HcGowan and Shapiro, The Comparative Study of Foreign Policy, for the few comparative African studies publ ished up to 1973. Patrick J. McGowan, "Africa and Nan-a1 ignment: A Comparative Study of Foreign Pol icy," International Studies Quarterly 12 (September 1968) : 262-295 and McGowan. "The Pattern of African Diplomacy: A Quantitative Comparison," ~ournai of Asian and African Studies 4 (july 1969): 202-221. Part of these aggregate data have been publ ished in Donald G. Morrison, et. al., Black Africa: A Comparative Handbook (Rew York: Free Press, 1972). The remainder are available from the address given in footnote 5. 9. See Thomas H. Johnson and Gary K. Gartin, "A Preliminary Examination of Foreign Conflict Behavior in Independent, Black Africa, 1964-1966," A paper presented to the annual meeting of the International Studies Association I (West) , San Francisco, Apri 1 1975. 10. The AFRICA data are being updated (for the years 1967-1969) by Ms. Martha Gephart with the support of a National Science Foundation doctoral research grant. Ms. Gephart's data should soon be available from the Consortium address given in footnote 5. 11. See C.A. McClelland and Gary D. Hoggard, "Conflict Patterns in the Inter- actions among Nations," in J.N. Rosenau, ed., International Politics and Foreiqn Policy (New York: Free Press, 1969), pp. 71 1-724, and C.A. ~IcClelland, et. al., "The Management and Analysis of International Event Data: A Corn- puteri zed System for Moni tori ng and Projecting Event Flows. " Los Angeles : Worl d Event/Interaction Survey Project, University of Southern Cal ifornia, 1971. (Mimeographed. ) 12. For a survey of event data see Phili~ Buraess and Richard W. Lawton, Indicators of International ~ehavior': An ~sgessment of Events Data ~esearch (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1972) and C.W. Kegley, et. al., eds., International ~vents. 13. Charles A. NcClelland, "Some Effects on Theory from the International Event Analysis Movement," Los Angeles: WEIS Project, U.S.C., 1970. (Mimeographed. ) 14. As discussed in Ronald G. Sherwin, WEIS Project Final Report (10s Angeles: School of International Relations, University of Southern California, 1973). 15. That is, there are n(n-1) or 32 x 31 = 992 directional or AHB pairs of states and n(n-1 )/2 or 496 non-directional pairs, where A * B. 16. Char1 es A. McCl el l and, "Many American Forei gn Pol i cies : The Stresses from Mu1 tiple Goals and Complex Administration," in M.B. Hickman, ed., Problems of American Foreign Policy (Beverly Hills: Glencoe Press, 1968), pp. 14-19. 17. Charles W. Kegley, Jr., "The Generation and Use of Events Data," in C.W. Kegley, et.al., eds., International Events, p. 99. 18. For a discussion of "issue-areas" see James N. Rosenau, "Pre-theories and Theories of Foreign Policy," in R.B. Farrell , ed., Approaches to Comparative and International Pol i tics (Evanston: Northwestern University Press, 1966), p. 67 and passim and C.A. McClelland, P.J. McGowan and Wayne R. Martin, Threat, Confl ict, and Commitment: Final Report of the Threat Recognition and Analysis Project (Los Angeles : International Relations Research Institute, University of Southern California, 1976), Part 11, pp. 32-36. 19. McClelland and Hoggard, "Conflict Patterns," p. 713. 20. Gary Hoggard, "Differential Source Coverage in Foreign Pol icy Analysis ," and Fobert Burrowes, "Mi rror, Ki rror, on the :/all . . . . A Corn~ari of Event Data Sources ," in J.A. Rossnau, ed., Comparing Foreiqn Pol icies, pp. 353-81 and pp. 363-406. 21. P. J. McGowan, James Kean and Robert Morle, "A Manual and Codebook for the Identification, Abstraction and Codinq of Foreiqn Po1ic.y Acts." AFRICA Project Research Report, no. 1. Syracuse: Department of Pol i tical Science, Syracuse University, 1972. (Mimeographed. ) , p. 1. 22. Burgess and Lawton, Indicators of International Behavior, p. 43. 23. Rosenau, Scientific Study of Foreign Policy, pp. 197-237. 24. McGowan, Kean and Morje, "A Manual and Codebook," passim. 25. WEIS stands for the World Event/Interaction Survey. See Sherwin, WEIS Fi nal Report. 26. Patrick J. McGowan and James Kean, "Coding Reliability of the AFRiCA Project Data. " AFRICA Project Research Report, no. 2. Syracuse : Department of Pol i tical Science, Syracuse University, 1972. (Mimeoaraphed.) , p. 8. 27. Ibid. 28. Our action categories are derived from the original WEIS codes, see Sherwin, WEIS Final Report, as modified by Walter H. Corson, "Measuring Confl ict and Cooperation Intensity in East-West Relations: A Manual and Codebook," Ann Arbor: Institute for Social Research, Uni versi ty of Michigan, 1970. (Mimeographed.), pp. 16ff. They are similar to the Corn- parative Research on the Events of Nations (CREON) Project, see, Charles F. Hermann, et.al., CREON: A Foreign Events Data Set (Beverly Hills: Sage Publ i cations, 1973). As argued by Raymond W. Copson, "Conflict in the Foreign Policy of African States, 1964-69," in P.J. McGowan, ed., Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Pol icy Studiel, vol . 1 (Beverly Hi 11 s : Sage Publ i cations , 1973), - pp. 199-200. 30. McClel land and Hoggard, "Conflict Patterns ," pp. 716-71 7 and C.W. Kegley, Jr., A General Empi ri cal Typology of Forei gn Pol icy Behavior (Beverly Hi 11 s : sage Publ ications, 1972). 31. I. William Zartman, "Africa as a Subordinate State System in International Relations," International Organization 21 (1967) : 545-564, and Zartman, "Africa," in James N. Rosenau, et.al., eds., Horld Politics (New York: Free Press, 1976), pp. 569-94. David H. Johns, "Diplomatic Activity, Power, and Integration in Africa" in P. J. McGowan, ed., Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Pol icy Studies, vol. 3 (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1975), pp. 85-105, and Johns, "The 'Normal ization' of Intra-African Diplomatic Activity," Journal of Modern African Studies 10 (December, 1972) : 597-610. Behavior may have occurred, but it was either so routine as to have been ignored by the editors of our source, Africa Research Bulletin, or it was secret, covert behavior that wi 11 not be known, if ever, until the relevant national archi ves are opened. As regards cl assi fied or secret behavior, it may be estimated to involve only five to ten per cent of all behavior, and when it is significant, such as the recent U.S. "covert" intervention in Angola, it often becomes known pub1 ically after the fact and is thus re- corded in an event data collection. W. R. Thompson, "The Regional Subsystem: A Conceptual Ex~lication and a Propositional Inventory," ~nternaiional Studies ~uarterly 17 (March 1973) : 89-117. For a summary of our knowledge on crises, see Charles F. Henann, ed., International Crises : Insights from Behavioral Research (New York: Free Press, 1972) . Fred N. Kerlinger, Foundations of Behavioral Research 2nd ed. (New York: Hol t, Rinehart and Winston 1974), argues that such activity is common to all branches of the social sciences. James N. Rosenau, The Adaptation of National Societies (New York: McCaleb- Seiler, 1970). For genuinely i nnovati ve work in attempting to measure psychological trai ts of leaders see Margaret G. Hermann, "Leader Personality and Foreign Pol icy Behavior," in J.N. Rosenau, ed., Comparing Foreign Pol icies, pp. 201-234. That is, for readers who know some elementary statistics, all we are saying is that national attribute variables should be used to explain statistical ly as much variance as possible in foreign policy behavior. The variance not explajned by such variables, when it is large, should then be considered as a consequence of leaders ' characteristics. Reasons why Somalia was so active, despite its small G.D.P., have been men- tioned earl ier on in this chapter. A useful exercise would be to frame an explanation of activity based upon factors other than resources and then do a case study of Soma1 ia to see if it fits your explanatory model. Li nton C. Freeman, Elementary Appl ied Statistics (New York: Wi ley, 1965), pp. 79-88. Ibid., pp. 162-175. But, it should be noted that relative activity levels seems to be a funda- mental characteristic of foreign pol icy behavior, see Charles W. Kegley, Jr., et.al., "Convergencies in the Measurement of Interstate Behavior," in P. J. McGowan, ed., Sage International Yearbook of Foreign Pol icy Studies, vol. 2 (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1973), pp. 309-339. McGowan and Shapiro, The Comparative Study of Foreign Pol icy, passim. A.B. Bozeman, Conflict in Africa (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975); L. Coser, The Functions of Social Conflict (New York: The Free Press, 1956); and L. Coser, Continuities in the Study of Social Conflict (New York: The Free Press, 1967). Taken from C.L. Taylor and M.C. Hudson, World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators, 2nd ed. (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1972), pp. 110-115. R.J. Rummel, "Dimensions of Conflict Behavior within and between Nations," Genera1 Systems Yearbook 8 (1963): pp. 1-50; Rummel, "Some attributes and Behavioral Patterns of Nations ," Journal of Peace Research 4 (1967) : 196-206; R. Tanter, "Dimensions of Conflict Sehavior within and between Nations," Journal of Conflict Resolution 10 (1966): 41-46. James N. Rosenau, Scientific Study of Foreiqn Pol icy, p. 31. Johan Gal tung, " International Relations and International Confl icts : A Sociological Approach," a paper presented to the International Socioloqical Association, September 1966; Marshall R. Singer, Weak States in a 'lorld of Powers (New York: Free Press, 1972); and Singer, "The Foreign Policies of Small Developing States," in J.N. Rosenau, et.al., eds., World Politics: An Introduction (New York : Free Press, 1976), pp. 263-290. McGowan, "Africa and Non-a1 ignment ," and McGowan, "The Pattern of African Diplomacy. " Published studies of African foreign policy decision making and organization are: T.M. Shaw, "The Foreign Policy System of Zambia,"African Studies Review 19 (April 1976) : 31-66; I .W. Zartman, "Decision-making among African Govern- ments on Inter-Afri can Affai rs," Journal of ~evelo~ment 2 (January 1966): 98-119; D.G. Anqlin, "Zambia and the Recoanition of Biafra." African Review 1 (September 1977): 102-136; M.A. East, "Foreign Policy ~akin~ Small States: Some theoretic Observations Based on a Study of the Uganda Ministry of Foreign Affairs," Pol icy Sciences 4 (December 1973) : 491-508; M. Dei-Anang, The Administration of Ghana's Foreign Relations, 1957-1965 (Atlantic Highlands, N. J. : Humanities Press, 1975) ; S.A. Gi telson, "Why Do Small States Break Diplomatic Relations wi th Outside Powers? Lessons from the African Experience," International Studies Quarterly 18 (December 1974): 451-484; A.H.M. Kirk-Green, "Diplomacy and Diplomats: The Formation of Foreign Service Cadres in Black Africa," in K. Ingham, ed., Foreign Re- lations of African States (London: Butterworth, 1974) pp. 279-322; C.S. Phi 11 ips, Jr., The Development of Nigerian Foreign Pol icy (Evanston: Northwestern Uni versi ty Press, 1964) ; and 6. V. Mtshal i , "The Zambian Forei gn Service 1964-1972," African Review 5 (1975) : 303-316. As in, for example, Henry A. Kissinger, "Domestic Structure and Foreign Pol icy," Daedal us 95 (Spring 1966): 503-529 and Graham T. All ison, "Con- ceptual Models and the Cuban Missile Crisis ," American Political Science Review 58 (September 1969): 689-718. Patrick J. McGowan, "Dimensions of African Foreign Pol icy Behavior: In Search of Dependence," AFRICA Research Report, no. 3. Syracuse: Department of Pol i tical Science, Syracuse University, 1972. (~imeographed. ) P. J. McGowan, R. Lewis and H. Purkitt, Cu1 ture and Foreign Policy Behavior: A New Look at an Old Problem with African Data (Beverly Hi 11s: Sage Pro- fessional Paper in International Studies, 1977). 55. P.J. McGowan and K.P. Gottwald, "Small State Foreign Policies: A Compara- tive Study of Participation, Conflict and Political and Economic Dependence," International Studies Quarterly 19 (December 1975): 469-500. 56. Brian W. Tornlin, "Relative Status and Foreign Policy Behavior," Journal of Conflict Resolution, forthcoming, 1977. 57. As described in footnote 5. ACP States. See European Economi c Communi ty Africa, Central, .js a subsystem, 208-21 1 Africa, East. Set also Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda as a subsystem, 208-211 conflicts in, 141-153 regional integration in, 126-156 Africa, Equatorial, as a subsystem, 210 Africa, Southern as a subsystem, 208-21 1 Angola in, 108-110, 118 Botswana in, 114-116 Lesotilo in, 114-116 Malawi in, 113-114 Mozambique in, 110-112 Namibia in, 105-107 regional relations in, 90, 105-121 , 146-147 Republic of South Africa in, 105-121 Rhodesia in, 107-108 Swaziland in, 114-1 16 Tanzania in, 116 Zaire in, 116 Zambia in, 112-113 Africa, West, as a subsysteni, 208-211 AFRICA Project. See African Foreign Relations and International Conflict Analysis Africa Research Bulletin, as a data source for the AFRICA project, 196 African Foreign Relations and International Conflict Analysis (AFRICA), 178-173, 790-241 coder reliability of data in, 197 coding rules for, 199-201 data coll ecti ng procedures for, 196-1 97 data set for, 193-201 data source, 196 operational i zation of data for, 195-196 updating of data for, 237n African uni ty. See Pan-Africanism Afro-Asian People's Solidarity Conference (May, 1965), 21 3 Arnery, L.S., on unification of East Africa, 130-131, 133 Amin, Idi, 126, 140, 141, 143, 145, 147, 149, 151, 154 Angol a and Cuba, 109-110 and the USA, 18 and the USSR, 19 civil war in, 109 in Southern African subsystem, 107-110, 118 Apartheid. See Republic of South Africa Arab states, relations with Africa, 11-12 Armed Forces Movement (of Portugal ) Africa policy of, 109-110 Arusha Declaration, 139 Azania. See Republic of South Africa Ba~anda, 137, 143 o~~osition to East African integration, 131, 134 Balkanization, 13C) Eanda, H. Xarnuzu, 113-114 Benguela Railway, 108, 116 Benin. See Dahomey Botswana foreiun policy of, 215 in Southern Africa subsystem, 114-1 16 Boundaries. See a1 so Conflict, boundary and domestic conflict, 162, 163, 175-176 and international conflict, 159-186 antecedent, 161 - 162 artificial nature of, in Africa, 7, 159-160 consequent, 161 - 162 derivation of, in Africa, 7, 159-161, 163 functions of, 159-160 superimposed, 161-186 Bourgeoisie, comprador. See Elites Bri tai n. See Great ~ri British South Africa Company, 107 Burundi , foreign pol i cy of, 223-228 Cabinda, 109, 116 Caborra Bassa Hydroelectric Project, 11 1 Cameron, Sir Donald, 132 Cartel s , international , 48-49 Case study examples of, 8-10 methods of, 172, 152, 190 Center, as power elite of state, 91-95 defined, 91 Central African Federation, 128 c.reation of, arouses fears in East Africa, 134 Central Legislative Assembly (East Africa), 133 Chad, and conflict with Ethiopia and Sudan, 171 China, Peoples Republ ic of. See Peoples Republ ic of China Cohen, Governor Sir Andrew, and the Kabaka Crisis, 134 Colonial - settlers defined, 96 in conflict with metropol i tan government, 96-101 in Kenya, 130-1 32 in South Africa, 98-99, 101, 103 role in dependency relations, 96-103 Cornpari son examples of, 10-12 in the study of foreign qolicy, 192-203, 198, 215-217, 222-223 Conference of €as t Af ri can Governors, 1 36 Conflict, boundary, 161-186, 228-230. See also individual countries involved in and ethnic population overhang, 164-168, 172-173, 180 and sub-imperial ism, 71 el i tes as a cause of, 170-1 71 , 174, 180-1 82 (3 ah C c, 79- h V) 0 ru W -4- aJ 0 b rn 0 0 7 3 v, KJ s - - U ru ru 0 U r--KJ h .I-- a r- L 0 L a Im rcl b Ce V, CnKJ u 7 u3 a t I -A 3 cO w c-, 0 e- U3 m 7 b - .- n - - ru C LD %-I- CV W N 0 -0 0 cn m m D Wc3 M m r\ 7 0 aJKJ UNCO CV M cO N M N V) LA +-) -r I CU I- I Lo ln 7 30-1 -~CV m cv .. co m I ru rdr Q-N I N s P - - 0.r CNM N CI . r N v Lo aJ 0 N 7 a rd U O -CV - 7 Q, n L m 0 m C h 0 N .r - c, ru m 7 -r S - U 0 N O '7 C\J m M %- N C-, u7 W t' .r v, v,+-'a3OL a mt-- aJ %E -m+ +'00 .rUCOClJ5ul r- a .r L n LnO KJ aJ m s w " v, m-r't- CI C, m .r aJ KJ N a r-fU0 IC b V, aJ Z E h N LO -0 o -C a mmb .r - E lea, e. N -a, c, 1I c 0 b - d' t 0 -t' F L 0 C, CW r I- KJ m L 303 KJ m~~O .r N aJ c m N 0. OCem umcu -m Lf)F I U >I 3 ? >M OM * L LO M +-'O 'r UN C 3 OW0 JZ ~faJ03 0 0 C r- my cr, e t' IOKJ N -A c, m mu ce o o c Omb . ~n rt3M.r 0 ^cV a D U r- 03 I n -0- V) 'r- e *-r m Lr Nt' " KY C .F cdm nmNf-a -4J S -r oam 70 mu v, IP- Em~f~le -m sr r-LO c I m a- m Ot'" evm -4- O,L >am om LO CCEC +J 0 Lm I 1-1-03 0 .r .r -I- .t- -7 m Orb m-0 - 0) a -7 a, -r m-03 Cb 003 ln n-F m mu10 TI CO .r-wt--- =-,+-a=-, rzsc,~~ at-0 0 - e-rn* -t'+ rT) rn -2 Eo c ^am -0 5CUOt'L C~CJU-I~J, cn~ u ^d‘t t' ^-.r 0 C) .r C ?a 00 0 a -J=.,--~ c 0 b m b 10 - mar% IF ., E ru nOC,(nUl- ah- o a, act w c - co - u-003 b~-ooomm am E mmm-7 I C u- Zh-r aJSr rn ruQ+Jn F aJ fZ I N-C-r eQwLn KJm OL Ar- L Clrbbw S 2C C r-+' VLI 3 CW carer- > 0 E rum -M I U~UI .r C 01-00 KJ I cnTtMC3 aJ m m~ araaa a33mam r-'e - ha 7 mg-mEa0 mC-0 -0 1 z,," iZ-r+--- m~‘+- Lm .r-@.J -ca,Quu= +-, Sm -or rural rQ~t-9-03-COc ml:~ eWEI .rE OLe (U>mL L IA .r+Jt+'Ga3 I 0- "a- -%ID 0mW 0 Q Om DW-r- 3 0 * ma 3- LFUI a, a, sa L RSWVU -- nt'-r om- t t mu c rn u -c a.7 vQ: C3:v mCC+ LO EO 0 KS-Ql+--r ++J- .r-rCC'+-mm a, st' I .r 0 r c LLf)-.r-r c'+- .r C C3I.r m UOOaJ aJ +-> I CL I --7 0 0 Q Q) 5 C Lh C.r 0 0 0 L 0 0- m'O mm > C% C CSt-- > C- CCC a3.ra,UZaL it+ * -~~.r- W t ht 0-Q U-I Ut- C C r V U U U* 3 0 U? U 0 U rdw- nC::C-)mm'e~OOLat'Q,.rL.r~T].r mUO U.r+-'.rO$~.r.r~-ra,.r-r< .rLa7QI LQI +J.F~~JKJ UUKJ-KJ~~,~'+-~~C~ L~LL a'+-- U aJt'Wt'r ant'., rr~ >'+-+-' 13 h~.rC, L a, V) L-? a).? uC, Q CC %.FCC'+- KJ aC,+ '+--r C. a E-r .r.rWt, o m%- I a I a 0 Q) 0% L GJWU 3 miel& ahL 0 u4 C3: E<< aJ r[Jam m mm m m 0 0 0 0 LX3KJma a, aJ aha KJ aKJ m rt] o o 0 o 0vonnn na maw w ww W W East African Development Bank, 140, 142 East African Harbors Corporation, 140, 147 demise of, 148-149 East African High Court of Appeals, 136 demise of, 147 East African riavy, 136 demise of, 139, 147 East African Posts and Teleconmunications Corporation, 136, 140, 147 demi se of, 149 East Af ri can Tourist 9oard demise of, 139, 147 East African Railways Corporation, 140, 146, 147 demise of, 148 Economic Commission for Africa (ECA), 45 and sub-imperial ism, 68 Economic Cornmuni ty of West African States (ECOIdAS), 14, 127, 128, 154 and sub-imperial ism, 68 Egypt, and the Soviet Union, 63 El i tes as a cause of boundary conflict, 170-171, 174, 180-182 transnational, 49-53, 57, 53, 62, 74-75, 92-93 Entente. See Conseil de 1'Entente Entebbe aid, 141 Ethiopia and conflict with Somali Republic, 71, 164-170, 132, 205, 210, 213 and conflict with Sudan and Chad, 171 foreign policy of, 209, 211 Ethni c popul ati on overhang as a cause of international conflict, 164-168, 172-173, 180, 182 defined, 164 EurAfrica concept, 15, 60 European Economic Comnuni ty (EEC) , 45 functional integration and the, 129, 153 relations of African states with, 15, 59-60 Events data, 10-11, 178-179. See also African Foreign Relations and International Conflict Analysis analysis of, 198-235 Charles A. McClelland and, 194-196 definition of, 194-195 inclusiveness of, 238n Factor analysis, 173 Federation of Rhodesi a and Nyasal and. - See Central Afri can Federation FNLA, 109-110 Foreign pol icy, African, 39-41. See a1 so Non-a1 ignment and individual states and the AFRICA project, 185-236 and the Middle East, 11 -12 bibliography of studies of, 8-22 boundaries and, 161-1 86 conflict in, 204, 213-214, 223-230 cooperative behavior in, 204-207 dependency and, 51-57, 59 influence of colonial experience on, 184-186, 210 infl uence of doines tic fzctors apor,, 1C3-:66 i nfl uence of extern?? fzctors uvon , 183-1 86 internatiofial organization as a fccus of, 12-15 patterns of, 198-235 self-reliance and, 72-73 time-series ~rofi of, 212-214 types and frequences of interactions in. 2Q1-237, 21 5-223 Forei qn ~ol the study of, 190-235 and concept of nu1 ti ol e forei gn poi i ci es, 195 and excrlanatory val ue of "indi vi dual variables", 21 7 case study method for, 8-10, 190-191, 194 comoarati ve study method for, 10-17. 191-193, 198, 215-21 7, 222-223 need for intersubjectively communicable know1 edcje in, 132 role of typologies in, 191 scientific approach to, 191-192, 217 France, and arms sales in Africa, 65-66 Frelimo, 109, 115, 116, 118 Fringe of state, 91 -95 defined, 91 Gamma, as a measure of association, 220 General Fund Services (East Africa), 150 Germany. See also kest Germany as colonial power in Togoland, 166 complaints of, against formation of common postal arrangements in Eastern Af ri ca , 1 36 demand for return of Tanaanyika by, 132 Ghana and conflict with Entente states, 205, 207, 211, 213 and conflict with Togo, 165-166, 170, 228 and conflict with Upper Vol ta, 170 foreign pol icy of, 198, 209, 21 1 , 21 5, 223-229 Great Britain Africa policy of, 21 and Pjngola, 101 and arms sales in Africa, 65-66 and army mutiny in East Africa, 144 and ~hodesia, 107-108 colonial policies of, in East Africa, 129-137, 144 Gui nea and conflict with Entente states, 214 relations of, with West African states, 207, 230 High Commission Territories. See Botswana, Lesotho - and Swazi land Horn of Africa. See also Ethiopia and Republic of Somalia as a subsystem, 210 as an example of ethnic population overhang as a cause of conflict, 164-1 68 conflict in, 71, &7n, 164-168, 182 Soviet Union's interest in, 7 United States' interest in, 6-7 Hostility, as a cause of boundary conflict, 169-170, 174, 183 Hypothesi s methods of testing, 177-180, 218-222, 228 null, 218-222 Idiographic studies. - See Case study method Indian Ocean Soviet Union's interest in, 7 United States' interest in, 6-7 Indirect rule in Kenya, 132 Inequalities. See also Middle powers - and Sub-imperialism between states, 46-51, 55, 62, 66-68, 75-76, 90-101 within states, 49-51, 55, 67, 91, 143-144 Intepration, bilateral. 128 Integration, regional, 58, 126-128. See also names of specific regional orsani za tions and sub-imperialism, 66-72 bibliography of studies on, 12-15 functional, 128-156 goals of, 126, 129 in East Africa, 14, 126-156 in Europe, 129 in Southern Africa, 116-1 17 in West Africa, 14 political, 127-129 problem of unequal distribution of gains in, 67, 132, 133, 136, 137-140, 150-152 requirements for success of, 129, 153-1 56 Inter-Universi ty Comni ttee for East Africa, 145 Interdependence of African states, 42, 44-45, 58, 72-76 Intermediary power. See Middle power International Court of Justice, and South West Africa, 4, 106 International law, African, 43 international organization. See also names of specific organizations as a target of African foreign pol icy actions, 231-232 bibliography of studies on. 12-15 functional, and African regionalism, 210-211 in Africa, 42-43 Israel , 63 and Entebbe Raid, 141 relations of, with African states, 11-12, 13 Japan and sub-imperial ism, 68 frequency of interactions of, with African states, 230-231 Johnston, Sir Harry, on unification of East Africa, 130 Joint Economic Council (East Africa), 133 Kabaka Crisis (of 1953), 134 Kabaka Mutesa, 134 Kampala Agreement of 1964, 138-139. See also Treaty for East African Cooperation Kenatco trucking firm, 148 Kenya, 126- 156 and conflict with Somali Republic, 164-168, 182, 205, 210, 213 and crrflict with Tanza~ia, 126, 141-152 and cc '1 ict with Ugands, 141 -152 as ecr nit center of East Africa, 16, 1313-140, 150-151 condi tlons in, 144 foreign ~olicy 145, 149 ideological views of government of, 131-143 white settlers in, 130-1 32 Kenya African iiational Union (KANU) , 143 Kenya tta, Jom, 137, 140 Khana, Sir Seretse, 115 Ki kuyu, 143 Kuanda, Kenneth, 9 Labor. See Migration Labor aristocracy , 52, 56-57 Land-locked states, 7, 47, 58, 114-115, 130, 138 foreian policies of, 198 Leabua , Chief Jonathan, 11 5 League of Nations and South West Africa Manadate, 106 and Tanganyi ka Mandate, 136 Lesotho, in Southern Africa subsystem, 114-1 16 Lete Island, and the ?liger-Dahoney confl ict (1963), 170 Liberia, foreign pol icy of, 198 Libya, and Cganda, 145-146 Linkage, between domestic and foreign policy, 183-186 Machel, Samora, 111 Malawi and c,onflict with Tanzania (1967), 170 foreign policy of, 9-10, 215 in Southern Africa subsystem, 113-114 Mano River Customs Union, 127 McClelland, Charles A., and events data, 194-196 Middle East, and Africa, 11-12 Middle powers, 16, 46-49, 53, 58, 66-67. See also Inequalities and Sub-imperialism characteristics of, 94-95 economic relations of, with core states, 102-103 Republic of South Africa as a, 95-105, 116-121 Rhodesia as a, 96 role of bourgeois national ists in, 100-101 role of colonial settlers in, 96-100 U.S. relations with, 62 Migration, 2, 14 labor, in Southern Africa, 105, 110-112, 113-114, 115 Mombasa-Kampala ?.ajlway, 135 Mozambique, 109 and Tanzania, joint air services, 150 economic pol icy of, 11 1 in Southern Africa subsystem, 110-112, 118 relations of, with Swaziland, 115 Rhodesia policy of, 111-112 MPLA, 109-119, 118 Mu1 tinational corporations (MNC). See also Parastatals and African el i tes, 49-50 and parastatal strategy, 54-56 Mutiny, of East African armies, 144 Nairobi, as center of economic development in Kenya, 143 Namibia. See South blest Africa National ism, African, 121 Neocolonialism, 44, 53, 54 New International Economic Order, 16, 75 and se? f-re1 i ance, 72 and U.S. policy in Africa, 61 Niqer, and conflict with Dahomey (1963), 168-170 Nigeria foreign pol icy of, 8-9, 20, 209, 211 relations with the Soviet Union, 20 Nkrumah, Kwame, 166, 170, 171 effects of loss of power of, on West African politics, 214 foreign pol icy views of, 21 1 views on African Unity, 127-128 Nomothetic know1 edge, defined, 191 -1 92 Non- a1 i gnrnen t , 41 , 57-66, 72 changes in content of, 57-58 lack of, in African foreign policies, 232 Northwestern and York Universities African Elational Integration Project, 193 Nyerere, Julius, 56 and agrarian social ism, 141-1 52 desire to unify East Africa at independence, 134-135, 137, 140 views of, on Southern Africa, 146 Obote, Yilton, 137, 141, la3 Operationalization of variables defined, 177-1 78 procedures for, 183n - 184n Organization of ~frican (OAU), 43-44, 127. See also Pan- Afri cani srn and African diplomacy, 205 bi bl iography of studies on, 13 role of, 12 Organ i za t i on of Senegal Ri ver States , 21 1 Ormsby-Gore W., on unification of East Africa, 130-131 Ormsby-Gore Commission, 130-1 31 Pan-Afri cani sm, 41 , 43-44, 72, 166, 21 1 bi bl iography of, 14-1 5 definition of, 126-127 Parastatals, 67. See also Mu1 tinational corporation strategy of, in African development, 45, 50, 54-57, 68, 78n Peopl es Republ i c of China Africa pol icy of the, 20-21, 63-65, 71 and military relations with African states, 66 and sub-imperial ism, 66 and Tanzania, 21, 6a-65, 140-146 frequency of interaction of the. with African states, 230-232. Peri~heral state, 91 -95 defined, 91 Pol i tical economv, 40-89, 90-1 21 bib1 ioqraphv of studies of, 16-17 Portuqal Anqola policy of, 108-110 attempts of, to aid whi te Rhodesian qovernnent, 137 effect of revolution in, on Southern African affairs, 117-118 Railway Council (East Africa), 135 Refugees, 7 Republic of Somalia. See also Somali and conflict with Ethiopia, 71, 164-170, 182, 205, 210, 213 and conflict with Kenya, 164-168, 152, 205, 210, 213 Daarood ethnic group in, 167-168 foreign pol icy of, 223 Republ ic of South Africa Africa policy of, 104 and Angola, 108-110, 120 and Botswana, 11 4-1 16 and Lesotho, 114-116 and Swaziland, 114-116 and the U.S.A., 17-18 as a middle power, 16, 95-105, 116-121 bi bl iography of, 4-5 colonial settlers in, 98-101, 103 foreign pol icy of, 5-6 international canpai gn against, 6 Malawi policy of, 113-114 mi 1 i tary expenditures of, 120 klozarnbi que pol icy of, 11 0-1 12 Namibia policy of, 105-107 nuclear weapons and, 6 Rhodesia policy of, 107-108, 118-121 Revolution,possibility of, in African states, 50-51, 57, 74 Rhodes, Cecil, 107, 117, 130 Rhodes i a as a middle power, 96 . bi bl i ography of, 2-4 civil war in, 4, 120-121 in Southern Africa subsystem, 107-108, 118-120 international sanctions against, 3-4, 107-108 Rhodesian Railways, 113, 115 Rosenau, James, and "individual variables", 21 7 "Safety val VP" hypothesi s as a cause of international conflict, 168-169, 171, 173-174, 180, 182 defined, 168 Sahel, 8 Salisbury, Lord, on artificial nature of African boundaries, 159-160 Sanctions, international and Rhodesia, 3-4, 107-108 and the Republic of South Africa, 6 Sawaba Party, 169 Selassie, iiaile I, foreign policy of, 211 Self-reliance, 41, 44, 58, 68, 72-76 defined, 72-73 in Tanzanian socialism, 142 Senegal River states, as a subsystem, 210-211 Settlers. - See Colonial-settlers Smuts, General Jan, 130 Sobhuza, King of Swaziland, 115 Socialism. See also State socialism African, 44, 62, 69, 72, 74, 121 agrarian, in Tanzania, 141-142 Somali ethnic group, 164-168, 182, 187n. See also Sepublic of Somalia Soma1 i Republic. - See Republic of Somalia South Africa, Republic of. See Republic of South Africa South West Africa bibliography of, 4 relations of, in Southern Africa, 105-107 Southern African Customs Union and problem of uneven gains from association. 67 , - Soviet Union Africa policy of, 19-20, 62-63, 68-71, 86n and communist parties in Africa, 62, 69 and Egypt, 63, 68 and sub-imperial ism, 68-71 Angolan policy of, 19, 109-110 - frequency of interactions of, with African states, 230-232 military relations of, with African states, 66 Nigerian pol icy of, 20 pol icy of, in the Horn of Africa, 7, 71 Spanish Sahara, conflict in, 8 Spinola, General Antonio, 109 State capital ism, 52-57. 73 in the Republic of south Africa, 123n State social ism, 52-56, 73. See also Socialism in Ghana, 211 sub-imperialism, 66-73. See also Middle powers and inter-African conflict, 71 defined, 66 Sub-system, 5-6, 15 and African regions, 207-214 and African relations, 205, 208 Sudan, and conflict with Ethiopia and Chad, 171 Swaziland, in Southern Africa subsystem, 114-1 16 TANU, 141-142 Tanzam Railway, 21, 64-65, 112, 116, 127, 146-147, 151 Tanzania, 126-156. See also Tanzam Railway and conflict with Kenya, 126, 141-152 and conflict with Malawi, 170 and conflict with LJgznda, 7, and Rhodesia, 116 and the Peonles Re?ubl ic of China, ?I, 64-65, 145-146 Arusha Declaration of, 139 conditions in, 144 foreign policy of, 145-147, 198, 215, 223 German demands for return of, 132 ideological views of, 141-152 in Eastern Africa subsystem, 116 in Southern Africa subsystem, 116, 145-147, 150-152 joint air services of, with Mozambique, 150 union of, with Zanzibar, 128 Testing, empirical compared to case study method, 172, 182 need for, 172 Togo, and conflict with Ghana (1955-1966), 165-166, 171, 228 Tourism. See also East African Tourist Board in East Africa, 149 Transnational organization, 42-43. See a1 so !lul tinational corporati3ns Treaty for East African Cooperation 0,139-140, 150, 153-155. See also Kampala Agreement Typology, and the conparative study of foreign policy, 191 Uganda, 126-1 56 and conflict with Kenya, 141-152 and confl ict with Tanzania, 71 , 141 -1 52 conditions in, 144 Ujamaa, 152 Union Douaniere et Economique de 1 'Afrique Central e (UDEAC) , 127 UNITA, 109-1 10 United Nations African foreign policy and, 11-13, 232 and South West Africa, 4, 106-107 Uni ted Piations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) , 45 3ni ted States of America Africa policy of, 17-19 and Israel, 61 and the Republic of South Africa, 17-18, 61 Angolan policy of, 18, 109-110 arms sal es of, to Africa, 65-66 as model of political integration, 127, 153 economic pol icy of, 61-62 frequency of interaction of, with African states, 230-231 policy of, in the Horn of Africa, 6-7, 71 relations of, with African middle powers, 62 role of, in Africa, 60-62 University of East Africa, dissolution of, 145, 147 Upper Vol ta, foreign pol icy of, 198 Vorster, Prime Minister, 118-120 West Germany, frequency of interactions of, with African states, 230-231 Wi twatersrand Native Labour Association, 110 World Bank, loan to East African Community, 149, 154 Zai re desire of, to annex parts of Angola, 109-110, 116 conflict between, and African states, 230 foreign policy of, 209, 211, 215 in Southern Africa subsystem, 116 Zambia. See also Tanzarn Railway and Rhodesia, 112-113 and Tanzania, 116, 146-147 and the Republic of South Africa, 112 and the Tanzam Railway, 65 economy of, 11 3 foreign policy of, 9-10, 113 in Southern Africa subsystem, 112-113 Southern Africa pol icy of, 108 Zimbabwe. See Rhodesia